World Economy
GA 340
1 August 1922, Dornach
Lecture IX
The formulas I tried to give yesterday are not, of course, mere mathematical formulas, but, like the ones of which I spoke before, they must be verified in life itself. Not only so; they must be conceived in such a way that they actually live within the economic process.
Today I must say a few things that may gradually lead us to understand the way in which these things do really live in the economic process. In the first place, everything that circulates within the total economic process must have a certain value. On the other hand we must also realise that many things can occur in the economic organism, the value of which is not immediately expressed in the economic processes themselves.
Let me give you an example that will serve as an introduction to some further economic ideas. Unruh has described very well, in his book on Economics, such things as the following, revealing as it were the more hidden connections. I give only one example which I myself have followed up and the truth of which I can vouch for purely as a matter of observation; although Unruh is a man completely wrapped up in State economics and, inasmuch as he thinks politically rather than economically, is unable in the last resort to bring these things into their right relationship.
I am referring to the price of rye in certain districts of Central Europe. It is a striking example of the complicated way in which things take their course in the economic process. If one hears big farmers or estate owners speaking of their work, one often hears them say: “We make nothing on the price of rye; on the contrary, we lose on it.” What does this really mean? To begin with, it means that these people cannot sell their rye as other things are sold—in the main, at any rate, today—where the price is composed of the costs of raw materials, the costs of production and a certain margin of profit. Taking the actual prices of rye in this way, we should find that they do not correspond to the costs of production plus a certain profit. On the contrary, they fall far short. And if, in balancing his accounts, a farmer were merely to include the actual market prices of rye, the values he would thus insert would undoubtedly influence the balance in a negative direction. As I said, we can follow the matter up and it is absolutely correct; the rye is sold, as we might say, “below cost price.” And yet it cannot be so in reality; it is impossible for this to go on in reality. Yet apparently it does go on. What happens is this: Rye yields not only grain but also straw; and farmers who sell the grain below cost price scarcely sell any of the straw at all. They use it on their own farms; they use it for their cattle and strike a balance in that way. What they lose on the rye is made up for by the manure they get from the animals. For this is the very best manure; there is no better. It is extremely rich in bacteria; it is the best manure a farmer can have. Thus from the standpoint of his accounts he gets the manure thrown in as a free gift and in this way, in the long run, a proper balance is struck.
We are thus obliged to posit an economic concept which, though it is most important, is comparatively little considered in the ordinary literature of Economics. The concept I would here establish is that of “internal economies” within the general economic life. You have an “internal economy” whenever an economic organism, a business, does business within itself—exchanges products within itself. That is to say, it does not sell such products outwardly or buy them from outside, but lets them circulate within the business itself. This I would call an internal economy as against the general social economy. Wherever such an internal economy is in force, it is quite possible for products to be delivered below the price which would otherwise be economically necessary. Needless to say, this implies that the forming of price within any economic domain is an extremely complicated chain of events.
Such connections, as I said, have been observed as matters of pure fact by our economists. There is another chain of events which I have touched upon from a certain point of view and which must now be regarded also from a different aspect. I mentioned a few days ago that we do not take in at a glance all the links in the economic chain. Imagine, for instance, that a cobbler falls ill and has an unskilful doctor to attend him. He remains ill and for three weeks cannot manufacture any boots; and so his products—the boots which he would have manufactured in the three weeks—are withdrawn from economic circulation. And now, I said, suppose he gets a skilful doctor who makes him well within a week, so that he gets an extra fortnight in which to go on making boots as before. Economically speaking, we can now ask: Who manufactured the boots? Economically speaking, undoubtedly—at this moment of the economic process—the doctor did; there can be no doubt about it.
Yet here again we come to another point. For you may ask: Did the doctor also get paid for them? No, in reality he did not; for you can make the following calculation. Reckon it up, according to the market: What did the boots the doctor manufactured amount to? And now if you draw up a rather full statement of account (it would have to be a very full one) you can set this off against what had to be spent on his training. And you will find, in all probability, that what was spent on his training was not so very different from the value of all the boots he manufactured and all the stags he shot; for it is not regarded as universally characteristic of doctors that they withdraw from economic life, for one week only, patients who would otherwise be withdrawn for three. Be that as it may—however the final balance emerged, we should not make a true calculation in the wider economic sense if we did not strike the balance in this way, setting off against the cost of his training the boots he manufactures, the stags he shoots (assuming that he cures the huntsman quicker than would otherwise have been the case), the corn he garners in, and so forth. Only, of course, the economic process is very complicated, and so the payment also proves extremely complicated.
From all this you can see: It can by no means be said with certainty, at any given place, what is the true source of payment for a given thing within the economic process. We must sometimes go far afield to discover what is the real source of such payment. People who look for mere simplicity in the economic process will never arrive at economic concepts coinciding with reality. They will not get far enough. They will not get at that, of which I said that it is really there behind the formulas of Price, Supply, Demand, etc. And these are the very things we must get at. What makes it so difficult to estimate the economic process rightly? It is because outlay and return are often so widely separated. That is why it is difficult to see clearly within the economic process as a whole what it is that is paid for, what it is that is bought, what is lent and borrowed, and what is freely given. For example, assume for a moment that what I advocated a few days ago is realised. Assume that the masses of Capital, arising in one way or another, are withdrawn from the tendency to get congested on the land and are given to the spiritual or cultural life—it may be in the form of Foundations, Scholarships or the like. These are free gifts. And now you will begin to see what happens on the one side of your gigantic ledger, for it must be a ledger that comprises the real economic life in its totality. The boots the doctor manufactures during the extra fortnight may actually contain an item which you must look for on the other side under the heading of “free gifts.” For it may well be that he had a scholarship to help him in his training, or that he benefited by some Foundation. In short, from this point of view you can raise the weighty question: What are the most productive transformations of Capital in the economic process? What are the most productive of all? Follow out such connections as I have just described: follow especially those portions of available Capital which go into Foundations, Scholarships and other spiritual or cultural “goods,” which in the course of time react to fertilise the whole process of spiritual production and enterprise of every kind. You will perceive that free gifts are the most fruitful thing of all in the whole economic process. We cannot arrive at a healthy economic process unless, in the first place, it is made possible for people to have something to give and, in the second place, unless they have the goodwill and intelligence to give what they have. Here, then, we have something which enters into the economic process in a very peculiar way.
It is remarkable, ladies and gentlemen, that this is something which we cannot extract from theoretical notions; it can only transpire from a wide range of experience; and a wide range of experience will give it you—the more so, the more you follow the matter up. Indeed, I would recommend you to keep this question in mind when you are choosing subjects for dissertations: What becomes of the free gifts in the whole economic process? You will find that the free gifts are the most productive of all. Capital freely given, gift Capital, is the most productive; loaned and borrowed Capital is less productive, in the economic process; and the least productive is that which stands directly under purchase and sale. That which is paid for immediately on a transaction of purchase and sale is the least fruitful in the economic process; that which depends on lending and comes into the economic process through the functions of invested Capital is of medium productivity; while that which enters into the economic process through free gifts is of the very greatest productivity—if only for the reason that the work which would otherwise have to be done to earn what is here given freely, or rather the product of that work, is actually saved. We freely give the available proceeds of the economic process, which would only do harm if they were left to congest upon the land.
We see, therefore, that at a given moment of its evolution the economic process gives no real information of itself. The “before and after” must always be taken into account, but the “before and after” cannot be taken into account unless it is based on the judgment of men who join together in association and who gain a corresponding insight into the past and the future. We have to build the economic process on the insight of those whose feet are planted within the economic process. Once more, we come to the same conclusion: It is, generally speaking, a difficult and lengthy business to estimate how the several factors in the economic process play their part in the whole of human life—I mean the material life.
From a certain point of view we can speak of Trade Capital, Loaned Capital and Industrial Capital within the economic process. Circulating Capital is more or less covered by these three categories: Trade Capital, Loaned Capital and Industrial Capital. Moreover, these three are contained in the economic process in the most varied ways. You must remember that such “internal economies” as we exemplified at the beginning of today's lecture are scattered everywhere throughout the economic process. And where you have an economic process taking place within a larger whole, it is really extremely difficult to say what are the respective contributions, quantitatively speaking, of Loaned Capital, Industrial Capital and Trade Capital to the general economic welfare. Yet it is possible to arrive at reliable concepts, if we extend our survey to a wide enough horizon.
Let us, to begin with, turn our attention to the economic life of entire nations, or State-economies as we must call them, according to the economic life of recent times. Take France, for instance; I take it only as one example. The world-economic connections of France, especially as they were before the War, and as they revealed themselves in their effects during the War, are a good example of how Loaned Capital works in the economic process on a larger scale. France always had a certain inclination to invest Capital in loans—that is, in effect, to treat “Loaned Capital” (investment Capital) literally as Loaned Capital, You are probably aware how these things penetrated into the political sphere, clearly illustrating the harmful effects of the coupling together of the economic life and the life of rights (that is, the political life), how it came out in the extensive loans made by France to Russia and Turkey. France exported a very large amount of Loaned Capital to Russia and to Turkey. Even in Germany, though Germany was not exactly in her good books, French Capital found a home—for instance, when the construction of the Baghdad Railway was begun. England withdrew, but France did not withhold her Capital from those who stood at the head of the undertaking—Siemens & Gwinner, for example. France, therefore, was in the main a lending country. In France one could see how Loaned Capital becomes involved in the whole economic process.
Further—and I am not defending or attacking anything, but simply describing things objectively—there is one historical phenomenon in which you can truly recognise what are the interests of Loaned Capital. When we turn our attention, say, to private “economies” or businesses, we shall always find, as any Bank will tell you, that the private business man is a peace-loving man. For he knows very well that his interests and dividends will be upset if, just as his Capital is nicely invested, a war begins to sweep through the economic connections of the world. Political economists always reckon with the fact that lenders are peace-loving people. That is the reason why it is always possible to say that France was innocent of the. War. For, the moment we want to prove that the War was not desired in France, we need only point to the interests of the numerous small investors and not to the interests of those who urged on the War. In France you always have in the background those who decidedly did not want the War. This fact of history may show us on a large scale what is equally true on a small scale. The man who lends—the man who is the happy possessor of Capital available for investment—is essentially the man who would like to see the economic life protected, if possible, from disturbance either by events outside it or by catastrophic upheavals within it. And the investor is all the fonder of tranquility because it saves him the trouble of having to form an independent judgment. He likes to be able to rely on the assurance of someone else that such and such is “a good thing.” In our age, though public opinion has a very good conceit of itself, there is really very little public opinion in the sense of judgment. We may say that in our time the possession of Capital available for investment is generally connected with a very strong faith in authority, both in the economic life and also in other respects. This, again, clouds the economic judgment to no small extent. Those, for example, who are in any way officially labelled very easily get money lent them. Personal credit is readily given to anyone with a title or some other official label. This is often the decisive factor. And according as this principle of authority is more or less cultivated, we see the consequences. For, in the one case, those who really have the stronger personal faculties will be enabled to enter productively into the economic process, while in the other case it will be simply men with a handle to their names—members of Chambers of Commerce and so forth—and often men who have got the name, not by reason of genuine ability but for some quite extraneous reason. It is one thing if such people are given the opportunity to work into the economic life, and quite another if a man has to depend on his genuine faculties being recognised by an untainted public judgment. Here, once again, something elusive enters into the economic life. (In a certain community it has recently become far too common a practice to use a certain word whenever one fails to keep pace with things with one's clear thinking. In many places recently, I have far too often heard this word, the imponderables. I wish to emphasise that I desire to avoid this word. All that I wish to point out is how these things, which we would like to take straightforwardly, become complicated, so that we may presently have to follow them up by somewhat curved and winding paths. It is unnecessary, as soon as this begins to happen, to have recourse to the convenient term “the imponderables,” which we have heard ad nauseam in certain quarters.) So much, at the moment, for Loaned Capital.
We will now go on to Industrial Capital. If we wish to study the essence and function of Industrial Capital we shall be able to do so especially well by observing the quick rise of industry in Germany in the decades before the War—though its history here is hardly an edifying one. We can study it here especially well, because, under the influence of the “enterpriser” spirit, Industrial Capital arose by direct transformation out of Loaned Capital to a greater extent in Germany in the last decades before the War than in any other part of the world. What I said in the first lecture is most decidedly true; In England, for example, Trade Capital was transformed gradually into Industrial Capital. For in England industrialism evolved out of trade, and it evolved far more slowly than in Germany, where it shot up with immense rapidity. Industrialism exists in its pure form where it transforms not Trade Capital but Loaned Capital into Industrial Capital. It can therefore be best studied in its pure form in the life of Germany.
Now the point is that Industrial Capital, if I may put it so, is really placed between two buffers. The one buffer is the raw product; the other is markets. Industrial Capital is obliged, on the one hand, to look around as far as possible for the sources of raw products and, on the other, to arrange for markets. This is not quite so easy to study in the example of German industry. In German industrialism you can rather study economically how Industrial Capital functions in itself. Still, the emergence of industrialism is evident in all countries during the nineteenth century and on into the twentieth, and so you can observe this standing “between two buffers” everywhere. Only you must search out the true facts. As I have said, it is a good thing to control the necessary direction—orientation—of our ideas, by taking things that can be surveyed as a whole; but you will find, if you are considering smaller economic territories, that extraordinarily difficult paths must sometimes be traced out. It is better to get your orientation and to derive your calculations from wide comprehensive regions. The paths grow easier if you observe economic organisms on a very large scale. Then, for example, you will perceive how as a rule the concepts of Force or Might (which often appear masked under the guise of Right or Justice) are realised most strongly where it is a question of opening up new sources of raw products. We can study this on a large scale, for instance, in the Boer War, where it was mainly a question of opening up the sources of precious metals. The Boer War was a real war for raw products. Of course it always showed itself in a kind of mask; nevertheless it was a war for raw products. Again, you have an example of how the economic life unfolds in a political way, playing over into the domain of political power—you have an example of this, for instance, in the military enterprises of Belgium which had the ivory and rubber of the Congo as their object. Thus you can see how the opening-up of sources of raw products takes place in the economic life. Or again, take the case of North America, which annexed the Spanish possessions in the West Indies, because it was looking for sources of raw products—sugar in this instance. In every case we can see how the search for raw products very easily drives the purely economic life into the political, towards the development of might or force. This is the one side—the one buffer, if I may say so.
With the search for markets it is different. For, it is easy to demonstrate from history that the search for markets does not lead into the political life in the same way. In this case the plain fact is that human nature does not tend so much to the use of force. We should have to go to the nineteenth century for a rather glaring example—I mean the so-called “Opium War,” whereby England conquered for herself the Chinese opium market. Even there it did not go quite so easily by purely military means; even there—if I may put it so—peaceful persuasion, peaceful politics, had not a little to say. For when things began to grow uncomfortably hot, a hundred and forty-one doctors were found to pronounce an expert judgment to the effect that opium is no more harmful than tobacco or tea. Here, then, politics—peaceful politics—played a certain part. Politics in any case are always difficult to keep out. You know the saying of Clausewitz: “War is the continuation of politics by other means.” Such definitions are all very well, but by the same method we could establish the proposition: “Divorce is the continuation of marriage by other means.” The relationships of life can always be represented in a particular light by using this kind of logic, and people admire it! Curiously enough, everyone sees through it at once if I say: “Divorce is the continuation of marriage by other means,” but when it is everywhere proclaimed that “War is the continuation of politics by other means,” they do not notice the absurdity, but on the contrary they admire it. In point of method, I should like to say: If we employ this sort of logic in Political Economy, we shall not advance a step. Speaking of this second buffer, of the hunt for markets, we must undoubtedly admit that a far greater part is played by human cleverness, which fluctuates between the extremes of slyness, astuteness, and wise economic guidance. In the arranging of markets a great deal could be seen at work of all three—particularly in the way they were arranged in those large economic domains which the States themselves had become as Politics and Economics coalesced. The States themselves did very much in this direction, by way of wise guidance, and also by way of deceit, cleverness, slyness and the like. Thus, the concepts which we require to form in respect of smaller economic domains, concerning the relation, say, between the single industrial undertaking and its sources of raw products and its markets, can only be made clear and palpable by considering these matters on a large scale.
If it is the functions of Trade Capital which we desire to study, we should take England, especially in the period when England made her great economic progress. This she did by means of trade; and consequently her Trade Capital continued to increase in such a way that England entered quite gently and imperceptibly into the new industrialism. At the time when industrialism was transforming the world, England already had her Trade Capital. In this early period, therefore, we can study Trade Capital most readily in England. In more recent times England has been chosen by Marx as a means of studying the economic functions of industrialism; but in the earlier period—the period immediately preceding the creation of modern industrialism—going back, that is to say, to the last decades of the eighteenth century, it is the functions of Trade Capital which we can best study in the light of England's economic destiny. Now it cannot be denied that here, either in the open or behind the scenes, the essential thing is always competition. Whether on the large scale, in the economic life of the nation as a whole, where it is mainly based on trade, or within trade or commerce itself, competition is the essential thing. Of course by the introduction of various ideas of what is decent and proper conduct, it may become very fair, but it is competition none the less. Productivity in trade—such productivity as to enable Trade Capital to be treated in the economic process so that it eventually takes effect as Industrial Capital—such productivity depends in the last resort on the tendency of Trade Capital to accumulate. And that is impossible without competition. Thus we shall study the functions of Trade Capital best of all by considering the function of competition in the economic life.
At the same time these things are connected with historical changes. This is indeed the case. Right up to the first third of the nineteenth century, if we are considering the world-economy which was gradually coming into being as a single whole (such as it was in a high degree before the War)—up to the first third of the nineteenth century, the economic processes of trade and industry still played the most important part in the economic life. The blossomtime—the classical age, if I may put it so—of Loaned Capital only began in the nineteenth century—indeed only towards the second third of the nineteenth century. And it is at this point that we notice the rise of those institutions which more especially serve the process of lending—I mean the banking system. The classical age of Loaned Capital, and with it the evolution of the banking system, falls into the last two-thirds of the nineteenth century and the first decades of the twentieth. With the evolution of the banking system, borrowing and lending develops on an ever larger scale—enters more and more as a prime factor into the economic process. But, at the same time, precisely in connection with lending, a remarkable phenomenon appears. Through the instrumentality of lending on a large scale, and accompanying the expansion of the banking system, the control of the circulation of money is withdrawn from man himself. The circulation of money has gradually become a process taking place—I can find no other word to express it—impersonally. Thus, as I said in my first lecture, the time has actually come when money does business on its own account, and human beings fluctuate up and down according as they are drawn into this whole stream of money economics, money business. They are drawn in far more than they imagine. Precisely during the last decades of the nineteenth century, the circulation of money has become objectified—it has become impersonal. This brings me to a peculiar phenomenon of the nineteenth century, particularly the end of the nineteenth century. In Economics, everything depends on an open-minded consideration of life as a whole; we must gain a clear vision of the whole of life. The phenomenon to which I refer appears, to begin with, in the psychological sphere, but afterwards plays a great part in the economic life. It is this: Conditions which were brought about in the first place by very real forces afterwards continue rolling on by a kind of social inertia, just as a ball will do when you have given it a certain momentum. They go rolling on and on, even after the original impulses have ceased to be active in them. Down to the first third of the nineteenth century, there were true economic impulses present in the whole system of loan and investment. Then, through the instrumentality of the banking system, these economic impulses began to change into purely financial ones; and in this process the whole thing became not only impersonal but unnatural. Everything was drawn into the stream of money, as it moved itself along. Pure money business, without any natural or personal subject—that is the end towards which, as the nineteenth century drew to a close, everything which had originally been upheld by a personal and natural subject was gravitating.
Strangely enough, this “subjectless” economic life, this “subjectless” circulation of money, was accompanied by another phenomenon. It was this: Political States themselves began to do business out of economic impulses; it was out of such impulses, for example, that they began to colonise. We shall see later what influence colonising has; de-colonising, too, will have to be considered in this connection. We can observe very well, as a real economic process, the significance of colonisation in the case of England. Fundamentally speaking, England scarcely ever went beyond the kind of colonisation which we may perhaps describe as “Imperialism with an objective content.” Such Imperialism, I mean, as contains a real economic substance—economic meaning. But if, on the other hand, you take the case of Germany, you need only look at the colonial accounts and you will see that German colonisation was burdened from the start with an adverse balance. There were at most tiny areas which showed a favourable balance. And in other countries too the tendency crept in, merely to enlarge themselves by acquiring colonies. Isolated people—Hilferding, for instance, in his book Finanzkapital, published in Vienna in 1910—actually called this process “objectless Imperialism”—Imperialism without an object.
These two modern phenomena are particularly instructive: on the one hand, the subjectless circulation of money, impersonal and unnatural; and, on the other hand, objectless Imperialism. Characteristic as they both are of large-scale economy, their appearance together suggests that the one depends upon the other.
Such a thing is purely psychological, to begin with, though in the further course it becomes economic; for if we have unproductive colonies we must pay for them—and that means that they at once affect the economic life.
So much for what we had to discuss today.
Neunter Vortrag
Die Formeln, die ich gestern versuchte darzustellen, sind natürlich nicht mathematische Formeln, sondern sie sind Formeln, so wie diejenigen, von denen ich schon früher gesprochen habe, die eigentlich am Leben verifiziert werden müssen. Und nicht nur das, sondern sie müssen so aufgefaßt werden, daß sie in der Volkswirtschaft drinnen wirklich leben.
Nun muß ich Ihnen heute einiges sagen, das nach und nach dazu führen kann, zu begreifen, wie diese Dinge volkswirtschaftlich leben. Wenn wir einfach darauf hinsehen, daß im gesamten volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß alles, was drinnen zirkuliert, einen gewissen Wert haben muß, so müssen wir auf der anderen Seite uns wiederum doch darüber klar sein, daß im volkswirtschaftlichen Organismus manches vorkommen kann, was seinen Wert unmittelbar in den Vorgängen der Volkswirtschaft nicht zum Ausdruck bringt.
Ich will Ihnen das an einem Beispiele klarmachen, das uns dann dazu führen wird, einige weitere volkswirtschaftliche Begriffe uns vorzuführen. Solche Dinge, die gewissermaßen verborgenere volkswirtschaftliche Zusammenhänge darlegen, hat ja sehr schön Unruh in seinen volkswirtschaftlichen Büchern dargestellt. Und ich führe hier nur dasjenige an, dem ich selber dann nachgegangen bin, und von dem ich sagen kann, daß es rein der Beobachtung nach stimmt, obwohl Unruh ein durchaus von Staatsökonomie getragener Geist ist, der also dadurch, daß er eigentlich nicht wirtschaftlich, sondern politisch denkt, die Dinge wiederum nicht in einen entsprechenden Zusammenhang zu bringen weiß.
Was uns aufmerksam machen kann, wie kompliziert sich die Dinge im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß abspielen, das ist zum Beispiel in gewissen Gebieten Mitteleuropas der Roggenpreis. Wenn man Großlandwirte hört, so werden sie sehr häufig sagen: Am Roggenpreis verdient man nichts; im Gegenteil, man verliert durch den Roggenpreis. Was ist damit eigentlich gemeint? Damit ist zunächst gemeint, daß Roggen für diese Leute nicht so verkauft werden kann, wie verkauft werden muß dasjenige, was zum Beispiel - wenigstens in der Hauptsache - seinen Preis heute in der Regel zusammensetzt aus den Preisen für die Rohprodukte, aus den Herstellungskosten und einem gewissen Gewinn. Wenn man in dieser Weise die Roggenpreise nehmen würde, so würde man einfach finden, sie entsprechen nicht dem, was die Herstellungskosten und ein Gewinn sind. Sie sind weit darunter. Und wenn man in dieser Weise die Bilanz gestalten würde für irgendeine Landwirtschaft, daß man einfach die Roggenpreise mit den Werten einsetzt, wie sie sind auf dem Markt, dann würde man eben einfach Werte einsetzen, die durchaus die Bilanz in einem negativen Sinne beeinflussen müssen. Wie gesagt, man kann der Sache nachgehen, und es ist absolut richtig, daß unter dem Preis -— wie man sagen könnte verkauft wird. Nun, das kann aber doch eigentlich nicht sein in Wirklichkeit. Es ist unmöglich, daß es in Wirklichkeit geschieht. Nach außen hin geschieht es aber durchaus. Was da vorliegt, ist dieses: Der Roggen liefert nicht nur die Frucht, sondern auch das Stroh. Das Stroh wird nur zum kleinsten Teile verkauft von solchen Landwirten, welche unter dem Preis Roggenfrucht abgeben. Sie verwenden es in ihrer eigenen Landwirtschaft. Damit versorgen sie namentlich das Vieh. Und dann machen sie ihre Bilanz so, daß sie dasjenige, was sie am Roggen verlieren, ausgleichen durch den Dünger, den sie bekommen von den Tieren. Nun ist dieser Dünger ja der beste Dünger, den man bekommen kann für die Landwirtschaft. Er ist außerordentlich bakterienreich. Und man bekommt auf diese Weise eigentlich den Dünger wiederum geschenkt — der Bilanz gegenüber geschenkt. So daß man also auf diese Weise tatsächlich einen richtigen Bilanzausgleich schaffen kann.
Sie sehen, hier liegt etwas vor, was uns nötigt, einen volkswirtschaftlichen Begriff aufzustellen, der außerordentlich wichtig ist und den Sie wenig berücksichtigt finden in der volkswirtschaftlichen Literatur. Dieser Begriff, den ich da aufstellen möchte, ist der der Binnenwirtschaft innerhalb der Volkswirtschaft. Also, wenn Wirtschaft in sich selber Wirtschaft treibt, also Tausch der Produkte in sich selber treibt, so daß also die Produkte nicht nach außen verkauft und von außen gekauft werden, sondern innerhalb der Wirtschaft selber zirkulieren — das möchte ich als Binnenwirtschaft bezeichnen gegenüber der allgemeinen Volkswirtschaft. Wo Binnenwirtschaft getrieben wird, haben wir es durchaus mit der Möglichkeit zu tun, daß nun sogar unter dem sonst volkswirtschaftlich notwendigen Preis Produkte abgegeben werden. Dadurch wird natürlich die Preisbildung innerhalb eines volkswirtschaftlichen Gebietes eine außerordentlich komplizierte Tatsachenreihe.
Nun können wir aber, wenn wir von diesen, wie gesagt, auch schon von Volkswirtschaftern als Tatsachen bemerkten Zusammenhängen ausgehen, zu einer anderen Tatsachenreihe übergehen, die ich schon berührt habe von einem gewissen Gesichtspunkt aus, die nun aber auch von einem anderen Gesichtspunkt aus angeschaut werden muß. Ich habe Ihnen nämlich vor einigen Tagen gesagt, daß man nicht ohne weiteres die volkswirtschaftlichen Zusammenhänge übersieht. Wenn man daran denkt, daß ein Schuster, sagte ich, krank wird und einen ungeschickten Arzt bekommt, so bleibt er drei Wochen krank, kann keine Schuhe fabrizieren; es werden also seine Schuhprodukte, die er in drei Wochen fabrizieren würde, der volkswirtschaftlichen Zirkulation entzogen. Nun sagte ich Ihnen, wenn er nun einen geschickten Arzt bekommt, der ihn in acht Tagen gesund macht und er also vierzehn Tage lang seine Schuhe fabrizieren kann, so kann man die Frage aufwerfen: Wer hat jetzt, volkswirtschaftlich gedacht, die Schuhe fabriziert? — Volkswirtschaftlich gedacht, hat sie zweifellos in diesem Augenblick des volkswirtschaftlichen Prozesses der Arzt fabriziert. Es ist ja gar nicht daran zu zweifeln.
Aber nun liegt hier wiederum etwas anderes vor, nämlich, es fragt sich, ob nun der Arzt sie auch bezahlt bekommen hat. Bezahlt bekommen hat sie der Arzt nun wieder nicht. Denn Sie könnten jetzt folgende Rechnung anstellen: Sie könnten marktmäßig berechnen, wieviel diese Schuhe ausmachen, die der Arzt fabriziert hat, und Sie könnten das aufrechnen, wenn Sie eine etwas längere Bilanz aufstellen, auf seine Ausbildungsausgaben, und da würden Sie sehen, daß seine Ausbildungsausgaben wahrscheinlich nicht sehr verschieden wären von all den Schuhen, die er fabriziert hat, von all den Hirschen, die er geschossen hat - denn bekanntlich haben Ärzte nicht immer die Eigentümlichkeit, daß sie einen, der sonst drei Wochen dem Leben entzogen wäre, eben nur acht Tage entziehen. Aber jedenfalls, wie auch dann die Gesamtbilanz sich stellen würde, würden wir die volkswirtschaftliche Rechnung nicht richtig aufstellen, wenn wir sie in einer solchen Weise aufstellen würden, daß wir nun die Schuhe, die er fabriziert, die Hirsche, die er schießt, wenn er einen Jäger früher gesund macht, das Korn, das er erntet und so weiter, nicht aufrechnen würden auf seine Ausbildung. Nur ist der volkswirtschaftliche Prozeß natürlich da ein sehr komplizierter, und das Zahlen stellt sich auch als ein außerordentlich kompliziertes heraus.
Sie können also daraus ersehen, daß es gar nicht so sicher ist, an irgendeiner Stelle zu sagen, wo heraus eigentlich etwas gezahlt wird im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß. Man muß manchmal weit gehen, um herauszubringen, von woher irgend etwas bezahlt wird. Wer etwa ganz glatte Einfachheit sucht im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß, der wird niemals zu volkswirtschaftlichen Anschauungen kommen, die sich mit der Wirklichkeit irgendwie decken. Er wird niemals zu dem gehen, was ich gesagt habe: es ist eigentlich hinter den Formeln gegeben: Preis, Angebot, Nachfrage und so weiter. Er wird nicht zu dem gehen. Man muß aber zu dem gehen. Nun aber, dadurch wird es ganz besonders schwer, den volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß in der richtigen Weise zu taxieren, weil man eben aus dem Grunde, daß, sagen wir, für Ausgaben manchmal die Einnahmen weit weg liegen, nicht so leicht in die Lage kommt, im gesamtvolkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß einzusehen, was bezahlt, gekauft ist, was geliehen ist und was geschenkt ist. Denn nehmen Sie einmal an jetzt, es realisiert sich das, was ich vor ein paar Tagen gesagt habe, daß diejenigen Kapitalien, die auf irgendeine Weise entstehen, entzogen werden dem Stauen innerhalb des Grund und Bodens und hineingeschoben werden in die geistige Kultur, dann kann das in der Form geschehen, daß man zum Beispiel Stipendien und Stiftungen gründet. Da haben Sie Schenkungen. Und Sie können also jetzt auf der einen Seite Ihrer großen, aber die wirkliche Volkswirtschaft umfassenden Buchführung erst sehen, daß in dem, was nun der Arzt fabriziert an Schuhen, die durch zwei Wochen gehen, vielleicht ein Posten steht, den Sie auf der anderen Seite unter der Rubrik der Schenkungen suchen müssen, wenn er etwa ein Stipendium gehabt hat, an einer Stiftung teilgenommen hat.
Kurz, Sie können, von da ausgehend, die schwerwiegende Frage aufwerfen: Was sind eigentlich die produktivsten Kapitalumlagerungen im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß, die allerproduktivsten? Und wenn Sie solche Zusammenhänge weiter verfolgen, wie ich sie jetzt dargestellt habe, wenn Sie namentlich verfolgen, was von verfügbaren Kapitalien in Stiftungen, in Stipendien, in sonstige geistige Kulturgüter hineingehen kann, die dann wiederum befruchtend wirken auf das ganze Unternehmertum, auf das ganze geistige Produzieren, dann werden Sie finden, daß das Fruchtbarste innerhalb des volkswirtschaftlichen Prozesses gerade die Schenkungen sind, und daß man eigentlich zu einem wirklich gesunden volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß nur kommen kann, wenn erstens die Möglichkeit da ist, daß Leute zum Schenken etwas haben, und zweitens den guten Willen haben, dieses zu Schenkende auch in vernünftiger Weise zu schenken. So daß wir hier kommen auf etwas, was in die Volkswirtschaft sich auf eine eigentümliche Weise eingliedert.
Und das Kuriose dabei, das ist etwas, was man nicht aus Begriffen herausschälen kann, sondern was nur eine umfangreiche Erfahrung geben kann; aber eine umfangreiche Erfahrung wird es Ihnen geben, je mehr Sie dem nachgehen - und ich würde es Ihnen sogar empfehlen, versuchen Sie recht viel Dissertationsthemen gerade nach der Frage hin zu orientieren: Was wird im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß aus den Schenkungen? - Sie werden dann finden, daß die Schenkungen das Allerproduktivste sind, so daß also Schenkungskapitalien das Allerproduktivste im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozesse sind. Weniger produktiv im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozesse sind die Leihkapitalien, und am unproduktivsten im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozesse ist dasjenige, was unmittelbar unter dem Kauf und Verkauf steht. Was unmittelbar unter dem Kauf und Verkauf gezahlt wird, ist das Unfruchtbarste im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß. Dasjenige, was auf Leihen beruht, was also in den volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß durch die Funktion des Leihkapitals hineinkommt, das ist, möchte man sagen, von mittlerer Produktivität. Dasjenige, was hineinkommt durch Schenkungen, das ist von der.allergrößten Produktivität, schon aus dem Grunde, weil diejenige Arbeit wirklich erspart wird, das heißt die Leistungen jener Arbeit erspart werden, welche sonst aufgebracht werden muß, um das Betreffende zu erwerben, was hier geschenkt wird. Geschenkt wird, was verfügbar aus dem volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß hervorgeht und den volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß schädigen würde, wenn es sich auf Grund und Boden stauen würde.
So können wir sehen, daß in einem Augenblick der Entwickelung überhaupt der volkswirtschaftliche Prozeß über sich selber keinen Aufschluß gibt, sondern das Vorher und Nachher unbedingt berücksichtigt werden muß. Aber das Vorher und Nachher kann ganz gewiß nicht berücksichtigt werden, wenn es nicht in das Urteil der Menschen gestellt wird, die sich assoziativ vereinigen, und die also auch über Vergangenheit und Zukunft eine entsprechende Einsicht haben können. Sie sehen, man muß bauen den volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß auf die Einsicht der in der Volkswirtschaft Drinnenstehenden. Das geht auch aus diesen Dingen hervor. Es ist überhaupt schwer, so ohne weiteres abzuwägen, wie beteiligt sind an dem ganzen Menschenleben, insofern dieses materiell ist, die einzelnen Faktoren im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß.
Von einem gewissen Gesichtspunkt können wir sprechen im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß von Handelskapital, von Leihkapital und von Industriekapital. Ungefähr wird das zirkulierende Kapital damit erschöpft, daß man es gliedert in Handelskapital, Leihkapital und Industriekapital. Nun, in der allerverschiedensten Weise stecken im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß diese drei Dinge drinnen: Handelskapital, Leihkapital und Industriekapital. Es ist nun wirklich — da überall eingestreut sind in den volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß solche Binnenwirtschaften, wie ich sie heute an einem Beispiel besprochen habe - außerordentlich schwer zu sagen in einem innerhalb eines größeren Ganzen sich abspielenden volkswirtschaftlichen Prozesse, welches, quantitativ ausgedrückt, an dem volkswirtschaftlichen Gedeihen der Anteil ist von Leihkapital, Industriekapital und Handelskapital. Man kann aber allmählich doch zu haltbaren Begriffen kommen, wenn man diese Dinge im Umfang eines größeren Horizontes betrachtet.
Sehen wir da einmal zunächst auf ganze Volkswirtschaften, Staats. wirtschaften, wie wir in Gemäßheit des neueren Wirtschaftslebens sagen müssen. Da haben wir, sagen wir zum Beispiel Frankreich. Nur als Beispiel hebe ich es heraus. Da haben wir Frankreich. An Frankreich in seinem ganzen weltwirtschaftlichen Zusammenhang, wie es vor dem Kriege namentlich war, und wie es dann in seinen Wirkungen im Kriege sich gezeigt hat, ist zu beobachten, wie im Wirtschaftsprozeß im Großen das Leihkapital wirkt. Frankreich hat ja eigentlich immer, man möchte sagen, eine gewisse Neigung gehabt, das Leihkapital eben wirklich anzulegen, also das Leihkapital als Leihkapital zu behandeln. Sie wissen ja, daß schließlich alles dasjenige, was dann in das politische Gebiet hinübergedrungen ist, woran man so klar hat sehen können die Schäden der Zusammenkoppelung von Wirtschaftsund Rechtsleben, also eigentlich von politischem Leben, daß das sich ja in bezug auf Frankreich abgespielt hat in der Beleihung sowohl von Rußland als auch der Türkei. Frankreich hat außerordentlich viel Leihkapital exportiert nach Rußland und der Türkei. Sogar nach Deutschland, trotzdem sonst im ganzen Frankreich eigentlich nie so recht gut auf Deutschland zu sprechen war, ist schon französisches Leihkapital exportiert worden, zum Beispiel im Anfang des Baues der Bagdadbahn, wo sich England zurückgezogen hat; aber Frankreich hat den Leuten, zum Beispiel Siemens und Gwinner, die ja da an der Spitze des Unternehmens standen, schon Leihkapital gegeben. Also Frankreich war eigentlich im wesentlichen ein leihendes Land, so daß man sehen konnte, wie Leihkapital eigentlich verstrickt wird in den gesamten volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß.
Ich will jetzt gar nicht für irgend etwas und gegen etwas sprechen, sondern lediglich objektiv darstellen. An einer äußeren historischen Erscheinung können Sie tatsächlich sehen, was für Interessen das Leihkapital eigentlich hat. Wenn wir den Blick wenden, sagen wir auf private Wirtschaften, so werden wir überall durch die Bank finden: der Privatwirtschaftende wird ein friedliebender Mensch sein; denn er weiß unter allen Umständen, daß in seine Zinsverhältnisse Unordnung hineinkommt, wenn er sein Leihkapital vergeben hat und über die wirtschaftlichen Zusammenhänge der Krieg hinüberfegt. Damit rechnen ja auch alle Volkswirtschafter, daß die leihenden Leute friedliche Leute sind. Das ist ja auch der Grund, warum es immer möglich ist, daß man mit Bezug auf Frankreich sagt, daß es keine Schuld am Kriege hat. Aus dem einfachen Grunde kann man es sagen, weil, wenn man beweisen will, daß in Frankreich nicht der Krieg gewollt worden ist, man nur auf die Interessen der Kleinrentner hinzuweisen braucht, nicht auf die Interessen derjenigen, die zum Krieg getrieben haben. Man hat immer in Frankreich im Hintergrunde die Leute, die durchaus den Krieg nicht gewollt haben. Gerade diese historische Tatsache kann uns im Großen zeigen dasjenige, was aber auch im Kleinen durchaus vorhanden ist: der Leihende, also derjenige, der sich Leihkapitals erfreut, der Leihkapital weggeben kann, ist eigentlich ein Mensch, der womöglich verhütet sehen möchte, daß die Wirtschaft gestört wird durch die Ereignisse, die nicht selber der Wirtschaft angehören, auch durch solche Ereignisse innerhalb der Wirtschaft selbst, die im wirtschaftlichen Leben besonders starke Erschütterungen hervorbringen. Derjenige, der Leihkapital zu vergeben hat, wird um so mehr lieben einen ruhigen Gang des Erlebens, als er sich selber sein Urteil im wesentlichen ersparen möchte und mehr darauf geben möchte, daß man ihm eben sagt: Da und dort ist eben etwas gut angelegt. - In unserer Zeit, in der das öffentliche Urteil zwar sehr eingebildet ist auf sich, aber doch im Grunde genommen sehr wenig vorhanden ist, in dieser unserer Zeit, da können wir sagen, ist zu gleicher Zeit die Möglichkeit, Leihkapital weggeben zu können, an einen außerordentlich starken Autoritätsglauben im wirtschaftlichen Leben und im Leben überhaupt geknüpft. Und das wiederum trübt außerordentlich stark das wirtschaftliche Urteil. Es bekommen diejenigen Leute leicht Geld geliehen, die in irgendeiner Weise abgestempelt sind oder dergleichen. Der Personalkredit wird gern demjenigen verliehen, der in irgendeiner Weise abgestempelt ist. Danach wird die Sache entschieden. Und nicht wahr, je nachdem überhaupt dieses autoritative Prinzip kultiviert wird oder nicht, je nachdem sehen wir auch, daß entweder die persönlich fähigeren Leute produktiv eingreifen können in das Wirtschaftsleben oder diejenigen, die nicht durch ihre Fähigkeiten, sondern durch andere Zusammenhänge - die soll es ja auch geben - Kommerzienräte zum Beispiel werden. Wenn die eingreifen können in das wirtschaftliche Leben, so wird es eben anders gehen, als wenn man angewiesen ist darauf, dal nur durch das Bemerken der persönlichen Fähigkeiten im rein Öffentlichen Urteil die Dinge vermittelt werden. Da greift wiederum in das wirtschaftliche Leben etwas ein, was man nicht so recht fassen kann. Es ist in einer gewissen Gemeinschaft in der letzten Zeit gar zu sehr üblich geworden, ein Wort überall dort zu gebrauchen, wo man mit den Begriffen so recht nicht mehr mitkommt, und daher ist mir in der letzten Zeit gar zu oft an den verschiedenen Orten das Wort «Imponderabilien » in die Ohren getönt. Ich möchte ausdrücklich betonen, daß ich dieses Wort hier vermeiden und darauf hinweisen möchte, wie sich dasjenige, was mehr gradlinig ist, verzweigt in dasjenige, dem wir werden nachgehen müssen auf etwas krummeren Wegen; aber es ist nicht nötig, daß gleich überall der Terminus Imponderabilien eintreten muß, wie es gehört werden mußte in der letzten Zeit an diesem oder jenem Ort bis zum Überdruß. Nun, das zunächst einmal ein kleiner Ausblick auf das Leihkapital.
Gehen wir zum Industriekapital über, dann werden wir ja, wenn wir das Industriekapital in seiner Wesenheit studieren wollen - wenn auch dieses Industriekapital ein recht wenig erbauliches Schicksal durchgemacht hat -, die Funktion des Industriekapitals besonders in dem Aufschwung der Industrie in Deutschland in den Jahrzehnten vor dem Krieg außerordentlich gut studieren können. Man wird das aus dem Grunde schon besonders gut können, weil ja in der Tat das Industriekapital unter dem Einfluß des Unternehmungsgeistes unmittelbar heraus sich verwandelte aus dem Leihkapital - mehr in Deutschland in den letzten Jahrzehnten vor dem Krieg als irgendwo in einem anderen Gebiete der Welt. Es ist ja eben durchaus wahr, was ich schon im allerersten Vortrag hier erwähnt habe, daß sich zum Beispiel in England nach und nach das Handelskapital umgewandelt hat in Industriekapital, weil der Industrialismus in England in einer langsameren Weise aus dem Handel heraus sich entwickelt hat als in Deutschland, wo mit einer ungeheuren Schnelligkeit der Industrialismus emporgeschossen ist, so daß in der Tat dasjenige, was, ich möchte sagen, Industrialismus in Reinkultur darstellt - und er ist in Reinkultur, wenn er nicht das Handelskapital umwandelt in Industriekapital,sondern das Leihkapital umwandelt in Industriekapital -, wenn man das studieren will, so kann man es insbesondere an der deutschen Volkswirtschaft studieren.
Nun, das Industriekapital, das ist ja eigentlich tatsächlich hineingestellt zwischen, ich möchte sagen zwei Puffer. Der eine Puffer ist das Rohprodukt, der andere sind die Märkte. Das Industriekapital ist darauf angewiesen, möglichst die Rohproduktequellen aufzusuchen und möglichst die Märkte zu arrangieren. Das ist nun nicht so leicht an der deutschen Industrie zu studieren. Am deutschen Industrialismus können Sie mehr rein volkswirtschaftlich studieren, wie, ich möchte sagen, in sich das Industriekapital arbeitet; aber Sie können immerhin, weil ja das Auftreten des Industrialismus in allen Ländern im Verlaufe des 19. Jahrhunderts und ins 20. Jahrhundert herüber bedeutsam ist im volkswirtschaftlichen Leben, dieses Stehen zwischen den zwei Puffern eigentlich überall studieren. Sie müssen nur eben die richtigen Tatsachen des wirtschaftlichen Lebens aufsuchen. Da wird sich Ihnen ergeben - und wie gesagt, es ist gut, gerade die Richtung, die Orientierung, die man braucht für seine Begriffe, an so überschaubaren Dingen sich vorzuhalten -, wenn Sie kleinere Wirtschaftsgebiete betrachten, daß Sie für Begriffsbestimmungen, für Begriffscharakteristiken außerordentlich schwierige Wege aufsuchen müssen. Sie erleichtern sich diese Wege, wenn Sie die Wirtschaften im Großen anschauen, wenn Sie an den Wirtschaften im Großen sich herausbilden Anschauungen, wie in der Regel sich am stärksten die Machtbegriffe und die manchmal in Rechtsbegriffe maskierten Machtbegrifle ganz besonders verwirklichen, wenn es sich darum handelt, die Rohproduktequellen zu erschließen. Wir können ja das im Großen studieren, sagen wir am Burenkrieg, wo es sich im wesentlichen darum gehandelt hat, Edelmetalle zu erschließen. Das ist ein richtiger Rohproduktekrieg gewesen. Er ist allerdings immer in einer gewissen Maskierung aufgetreten, aber er ist ein richtiger Rohproduktekrieg gewesen. Dann haben Sie ein Beispiel, wie sich entfaltet das wirtschaftliche Leben auf eine politische Weise, ins Politische, ins Machtmäßige hineinspielend, sagen wir in dem, was kriegerisch unternommen hat Belgien, um das Elfenbein und den Kautschuk vom Kongostaat zu erhalten. Da können Sie sehen, wie in der Volkswirtschaft die Erschließung der Rohproduktequellen vor sich geht. Oder nehmen Sie, wie Nordamerika die spanischen Besitzungen in Westindien sich angeeignet hat, weil es dort die Rohproduktequellen für Zucker aufsuchte. Also überall können wir sehen, wie das Aufsuchen des Rohproduktes das rein Wirtschaftliche nach der einen Seite hin ins Politische leicht hineintreibt, zur Machtentfaltung treibt. Das ist die eine Seite, der eine Puffer, möchte ich sagen.
Anders ist es mit dem Aufsuchen der Märkte. Und es ist schon durch die Geschichte leicht zu erweisen, daß das Aufsuchen der Märkte nicht in derselben Weise ins politische Leben hineinführt. Es entwickelt sich einfach nicht, aus der menschlichen Natur heraus, in derselben Weise die Entfaltung der Macht. Ein krasses Beispiel, das muß man schon im 19. Jahrhundert suchen, als sich England im sogenannten Opiumkrieg den chinesischen Opiummarkt eroberte. Aber selbst da ging es nicht so leicht mit dem Krieg, sondern da hat schon auch, ich möchte sagen, die friedliche Politik ihr Wörtchen mitgeredet, indem sich, als die Geschichte sengerig wurde, einhunderteinundvierzig Ärzte gefunden haben, die ein Sachverständigenurteil dahin abgegeben haben, daß der Opiumgenuß nicht schädlicher wirke als der Tabak- und Teegenuß. Also da spielte die Politik hinein, die friedliche Politik; aber Politik ist immer schwer fernzuhalten. Sie kennen den Clausewitzschen Satz, daß der Krieg die Fortführung der Politik mit andern Mitteln sei. Nun, solche Definitionen kann man immer aufstellen: denn man kann ja mit dieser Definitionsart auch zum Beispiel den Satz rechtfertigen, daß die Scheidung die Fortsetzung der Ehe ist mit andern Mitteln. Ja, man kann gar mancherlei Lebenszusammenhänge, wenn man mit dieser Logik vorgeht, in dieses oder jenes Licht stellen, und die Leute bewundern das dann. Komischerweise, da bemerkt es ein jeder, wenn ich sage: Die Scheidung ist die Fortführung der Ehe mit andern Mitteln. Da bemerkt jeder die Geschichte. Wenn aber überall deklamiert wird: Der Krieg ist die Fortführung der Politik mit andern Mitteln — da bemerken die Leute nicht das Kuriose der Logik, sondern sie bewundern das. Wenn man solche Logik, namentlich in der Volkswirtschaft, anwendet, das möchte ich methodologisch sagen, dann kommt man nämlich niemals einen Schritt weiter, wenn man solche Definitionen aufstellt. Wenn wir diesen andern Puffer betrachten, das Aufsuchen der Märkte, dann müssen wir uns allerdings sagen: Beim Aufsuchen der Märkte spielt eine wesentlich größere Rolle die menschliche Klugheit zwischen den Polen Schlauheit, List, und weiser volkswirtschaftlicher Führung. Es ist sehr viel von allen drei Gattungen in dem Arrangieren der Märkte, wie sie eingerichtet wurden namentlich von den großen volkswirtschaftlichen Gebieten, die die Staaten selber geworden sind, als sich die Politik mit der Wirtschaft verbunden hatte; es ist dabei von den Staaten selbst sehr viel getrieben worden, sowohl an weisheitsvoller Führung, wie auch an Listigkeit, Klugheit, Schlauheit und so weiter. So daß man für die Begriffe, die man sich nun für die einzelnen kleineren Wirtschaftsgebiete ausbilden will über den Zusammenhang zwischen der einzelnen Industrieunternehmung und ihrer Beziehung zu den Rohproduktequellen und zu dem Markte, daß man sich da doch eigentlich erst anschauliche Begriffe bilden kann, wenn man diese Dinge im Großen betrachtet.
Wenn man die Funktion des Handelskapitals studieren will, dann ist es gut, England zu studieren, und zwar vorzugsweise in derjenigen Zeit, in welcher England seinen großen wirtschaftlichen Fortschritt gemacht hat durch den Handel, wodurch das Handelskapital immer erhöht wurde, so daß eigentlich England ganz sanft und allmählich in den neueren Industrialismus eingetreten ist. In der Zeit, als der Industrialismus alles umgestaltete, da hatte England schon sein Handelskapital, so daß man für frühere Zeiten an England studieren kann das Handelskapital. Für neuere Zeiten hat ganz besonders Marx die volkswirtschaftliche Funktion des Industrialismus in England studieren wollen; aber für ältere Zeiten, die gerade der Schöpfung des modernen Industrialismus vorangegangen sind, in den letzten Jahrzehnten des 18. Jahrhunderts, wenn man zu diesen zurückgeht, dann findet man die Funktion des Handelskapitals ganz besonders in den wirtschaftlichen Schicksalen Englands. Und da allerdings, da muß man sagen, daß das Wesentliche dennoch immer ist, ob es nun mehr oder weniger offen oder versteckt hervortritt, sowohl in der großen Volkswirtschaft, wenn sie hauptsächlich auf Handel gestellt ist, wie auch innerhalb des Handels selber, die Konkurrenz. Gewiß, diese kann dadurch, daß allerlei Anstandsbegriffe eingeführt werden, eine sehr faire sein. Aber Konkurrenz bleibt sie doch. Denn dasjenige, worauf gerade die Produktivität im Handel beruht, wodurch gerade Handelskapital so behandelt werden kann im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß, daß es dann wirksam wird, zum Beispiel als Industriekapital, das beruht ja doch darauf, daß Handelskapital zur Zusammenhäufung führt, und diese Zusammenhäufung ist ohne Konkurrenz nicht denkbar. So daß man die Funktion des Handelskapitals ganz besonders gut studieren wird, wenn man die Funktion der Konkurrenz im volkswirtschaftlichen Leben ins Auge faßt.
Zu gleicher Zeit stehen aber mit diesen Dingen in Zusammenhang auch die historischen Verwandlungen. Es ist ja durchaus so, daß wir sagen können, daß bis etwa ins erste Drittel des 19. Jahrhunderts hinein, wenn man die allmählich entstehende Weltwirtschaft als ein Ganzes - vor dem Kriege war sie es in hohem Grade - betrachtet, daß bis dahinein die hervorragendste Rolle im wirtschaftlichen Leben die wirtschaftlichen Prozesse des Handels und der Industrie spielten.
Die Blütezeit, ich möchte sagen, das klassische Zeitalter des Leihkapitals trat eigentlich erst im 19. Jahrhundert, und zwar erst eigentlich gegen das zweite Drittel des 19. Jahrhunderts ein. Und damit ist dann zu verzeichnen in der geschichtlichen Entwickelung das Heraufkommen derjenigen Institutionen, die namentlich dem Beleihen dienen, das Heraufkommen des Bankwesens. So daß das klassische Zeitalter des Leihkapitals und damit die Entfaltung des Bankwesens in die letzten zwei Drittel des 19. Jahrhunderts und in die ersten Jahrzehnte des 20. Jahrhunderts fällt. Mit der Entwickelung des Bankwesens entwickelt sich immer mehr und mehr die Beleihung als dasjenige, was, ich möchte sagen, nun als ein erster Faktor eintritt in den volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß. Aber dabei hat sich zu gleicher Zeit etwas ganz Besonderes gezeigt, gerade beim Beleihen, nämlich das, daß nun durch das Beleihen im großen Stil unter der Ausbreitung des Bankwesens dem Menschen die Herrschaft über die Geldzirkulation eigentlich entzogen worden ist, daß nach und nach der Zirkulationsprozeß des Geldes ein solcher geworden ist, der sich - ja, ich finde keinen andern Ausdruck -, der sich unpersönlich abspielt; so daß, was ich schon erwähnt habe im ersten Vortrag, tatsächlich die Zeit heraufgezogen ist, wo das Geld nun selber wirtschaftet, und der Mensch bald droben, bald drunten ist, je nachdem er in diesen ganzen Strom der Geldwirtschaft hineingezogen wird. Er wird es nämlich viel mehr, als er es eigentlich denkt; denn es hat sich die Geldzirkulation gerade im Laufe der letzten Jahrzehnte des 19. Jahrhunderts verobjektiviert, ist unpersönlich geworden. Damit komme ich - und weil es bei der Volkswirtschaft darauf ankommt, daß man das ganze Leben in unbefangener Weise beurteilt, so müssen Ausblicke auf das ganze Leben gegeben werden -—, damit komme ich auf eine eigentümliche Erscheinung des 19. Jahrhunderts, namentlich seines Endes, auf eine Erscheinung, die zunächst psychologisch sich ausnimmt, die dann aber eine große volkswirtschaftliche Rolle spielt: daß Lebenserscheinungen, die sich inaugurieren aus Kräften, welche durchaus reale Kräfte im Lebenszusammenhang sind, daß diese Lebenserscheinungen dann wie durch eine Art von sozialer Trägheit weiterrollen, wie eine Kugel weiterrollt, wenn ich ihr einen Schwung gegeben habe, daß das Weiterrollen sich dann abspielt, auch ohne daß die ursprünglichen Impulse noch drinnen tätig sind. So haben wir durchaus volkswirtschaftliche Impulse in dem Leihsystem schon drinnen gehabt bis in das erste Drittel. des 19. Jahrhunderts. Da fangen diese volkswirtschaftlichen Impulse an, rein finanzwirtschaftliche Impulse zu werden durch das Bankwesen. Damit wird das Ganze nicht nur unpersönlich, sondern sogar unnatürlich; es wird alles in die sich selbst bewegende Geldströmung hineingezogen. Geldwirtschaft ohne natürliches und persönliches Subjekt, das ist dasjenige, wo hintendiert hat gegen das Ende des 19. Jahrhunderts das, was ursprünglich durchaus vom persönlichen und vom natürlichen Subjekt getragen war.
Und es ist eigentümlich, daß dieses subjektlose Wirtschaften, dieses subjektlose Geldzirkulieren begleitet ist von einer anderen Erscheinung. Das ist diese: daß die Staaten allerdings angefangen haben zu wirtschaften aus wirtschaftlichen Impulsen heraus, aus wirtschaftlichen Impulsen heraus zum Beispiel versucht haben zu kolonisieren. Wir werden morgen sehen, was für einen Einfluß dieses Kolonisieren auf das Wirtschaftsleben hat; auch das Entkolonisieren muß dabei betrachtet werden. Wir können zum Beispiel sehr gut beobachten in einem realwirtschaftlichen Prozeß, welche Bedeutung das Kolonisieren bei England hat; England ist im Grunde genommen kaum jemals hinausgegangen über das Kolonisieren, also sagen wir über den Imperialismus mit objektiver Substanz. Ich meine das Hereinbeziehen von wirklichen wirtschaftlichen Inhalten mit Imperialisieren. Wenn Sie aber betrachten zum Beispiel das deutsche Kolonisieren - Sie brauchen sich nur die Kolonialbilanzen einmal vorzunehmen -, da werden Sie sehen, daß das deutsche Kolonisieren zunächst ganz mit negativer Bilanz behaftet war. Es gab nur ganz kleine Flecke, die mit positiver Bilanz abschnitten. Aber auch bei anderen Staaten hat sich nach und nach wenigstens die Tendenz eingeschlichen, sich einfach durch Kolonien zu vergrößern. Das haben dann auch einzelne Leute wie Hilferding in seinem Buch «Finanzkapital», das 1910 in Wien erschienen ist, genannt «objektlosen Imperialismus ».
Sie können also von diesen zwei Erscheinungen als eben außerordentlich lehrreichen Erscheinungen in der neueren Zeit sprechen: auf der einen Seite von dem sowohl in natürlicher wie in persönlicher Beziehung subjektlosen Geldzirkulieren, und auf der anderen Seite vom objektlosen Imperialismus in der großen Wirtschaft. Das sind durchaus zwei Erscheinungen, die in der neueren Zeit dastehen, wie wenn das eine das andere bedingt hätte im ganzen Zusammenhang. Man kann sagen: Rein Psychologisches ist es, wovon man ausgehen kann; aber es wird im weiteren Verlauf ein Wirtschaftliches; denn wenn man unproduktive Kolonien hat, so muß das negativ gezahlt werden. Also es greift nachher schon in das Wirtschaftsleben ein.
Nun, das sind die Dinge, die wir heute zu besprechen hatten.
Ninth Lecture
The formulas I attempted to present yesterday are, of course, not mathematical formulas, but rather formulas, like those I have spoken of before, that must actually be verified in real life. Not only that, but they must be understood in such a way that they truly exist within the national economy.
Today, I must tell you a few things that will gradually help you understand how these things work in the economy. If we simply consider that everything that circulates within the overall economic process must have a certain value, we must also be aware that there may be some things within the economic organism that do not directly express their value in the processes of the economy.
I would like to illustrate this with an example that will then lead us to introduce some further economic concepts. Such things, which reveal more hidden economic connections, have been beautifully described by Unruh in his books on economics. And I will only cite here the one that I myself have investigated and can say is correct based purely on observation, even though Unruh is thoroughly imbued with the spirit of state economics and, because he thinks politically rather than economically, does not know how to put things into the proper context.
What can draw our attention to how complicated things are in the economic process is, for example, the price of rye in certain areas of Central Europe. If you listen to large-scale farmers, they will very often say: You can't make any money on the price of rye; on the contrary, you lose money on the price of rye. What do they actually mean by this? First of all, they mean that rye cannot be sold in the same way as other products, whose price today is generally made up of the prices of the raw materials, the production costs, and a certain profit margin. If rye prices were taken in this way, one would simply find that they do not correspond to the production costs and profit. They are far below that. And if one were to draw up the balance sheet for any agricultural business in this way, simply entering the prices of rye at their market values, one would simply be entering values that would inevitably have a negative impact on the balance sheet. As I said, one can look into the matter, and it is absolutely true that it is being sold below price, as one might say. Well, that can't actually be the case in reality. It's impossible for that to happen in reality. Outwardly, however, it certainly does happen. What we have here is this: rye not only provides the grain, but also the straw. Only a small portion of the straw is sold by farmers who sell rye grain below the price. They use it in their own farming. They use it to feed their livestock. And then they balance their books so that what they lose on the rye is offset by the fertilizer they get from the animals. Now, this fertilizer is the best fertilizer you can get for agriculture. It is extremely rich in bacteria. And in this way, you actually get the fertilizer for free — free in terms of the balance sheet. So in this way, you can actually achieve a real balance.
You see, here we have something that requires us to establish an economic term that is extremely important and that you will find little mention of in economic literature. The concept I would like to establish is that of the domestic economy within the national economy. So, when the economy conducts business within itself, i.e., exchanges products within itself, so that the products are not sold externally and purchased from outside, but circulate within the economy itself — I would like to refer to this as the domestic economy as opposed to the general national economy. Where a domestic economy is pursued, we are certainly dealing with the possibility that products are now being sold even below the price that would otherwise be necessary in economic terms. This, of course, makes price formation within an economic area an extremely complicated series of facts.
However, if we start from these connections, which, as I said, have already been noted as facts by economists, we can move on to another series of facts, which I have already touched on from a certain point of view, but which must now also be viewed from another point of view. A few days ago, I told you that economic relationships cannot be easily overlooked. If, as I said, a shoemaker falls ill and is treated by an incompetent doctor, he will remain ill for three weeks and will be unable to make shoes; this means that the shoes he would have made in three weeks will be withdrawn from economic circulation. Now, I told you that if he gets a skilled doctor who cures him in eight days and he can therefore make shoes for fourteen days, the question arises: from an economic point of view, who made the shoes? From an economic point of view, it was undoubtedly the doctor who made them at that moment in the economic process. There is no doubt about that.
But now there is another issue, namely, the question of whether the doctor was paid for them. The doctor was not paid for them. Because you could now do the following calculation: you could calculate the market value of the shoes that the doctor made, and you could offset that against his training expenses if you draw up a slightly longer balance sheet, and you would see that his training expenses would probably not be very different from all the shoes he has made, from all the deer he has shot—because, as we know, doctors do not always have the peculiarity of saving someone who would otherwise have three weeks left to live for only eight days. But in any case, whatever the overall balance sheet would look like, we would not be setting up the economic calculation correctly if we set it up in such a way that we did not offset the shoes he manufactures, the deer he shoots, the grain he harvests, and so on, against his education. But of course, the economic process is very complicated, and the figures also turn out to be extremely complicated.
So you can see from this that it is not at all certain to say at any point where something is actually paid for in the economic process. Sometimes you have to go a long way to find out where something is paid for. Anyone who seeks complete simplicity in the economic process will never arrive at economic views that correspond in any way to reality. They will never arrive at what I have said: it is actually given behind the formulas: price, supply, demand, and so on. They will not arrive at that. But one must come to that. Now, however, this makes it particularly difficult to assess the economic process in the right way, because, precisely for the reason that, let's say, expenditure is sometimes far removed from income, it is not so easy to see in the overall economic process what is paid for, what is bought, what is borrowed, and what is given as a gift. For suppose now that what I said a few days ago comes true, that the capital that arises in some way is withdrawn from the accumulation within the land and pushed into intellectual culture, then this can happen in the form of, for example, establishing scholarships and foundations. There you have gifts. And so, on the one hand, you can now see in your large-scale accounting system, which encompasses the entire national economy, that in what the doctor now produces in terms of shoes that last two weeks, there may be an item that you have to look for on the other hand under the heading of gifts, if he had a scholarship, for example, or participated in a foundation.
In short, based on this, you can raise the serious question: What are actually the most productive capital transfers in the economic process, the most productive of all? And if you pursue such connections further, as I have now described, if you pursue in particular what can go into available capital in foundations, in scholarships, in other intellectual cultural assets, which in turn have a fertilizing effect on the whole of entrepreneurship, on the whole of intellectual production, then you will find that the most fruitful aspect of the economic process is precisely donations, and that a truly healthy economic process can only be achieved if, first, people have something to donate and, second, they have the goodwill to donate it in a reasonable manner. This brings us to something that fits into the economy in a peculiar way.
And the curious thing about this is that it is something that cannot be deduced from concepts, but can only be gained through extensive experience; however, the more you pursue it, the more extensive your experience will be—and I would even recommend that you try to orient a great many dissertation topics toward the question: What becomes of gifts in the economic process? You will then find that donations are the most productive, so that donation capital is the most productive in the economic process. Less productive in the economic process is loan capital, and the least productive in the economic process is that which is directly related to buying and selling. What is paid directly under buying and selling is the most unproductive in the economic process. That which is based on loans, that which enters the economic process through the function of loan capital, is, one might say, of medium productivity. That which enters through gifts is of the greatest productivity, if only because the work is actually saved, that is, the performance of that work is saved which would otherwise have to be expended to acquire what is being given here. What is donated is what is available from the economic process and would damage the economic process if it were to accumulate on the ground.
Thus, we can see that at any given moment in its development, the economic process does not reveal anything about itself, but that the before and after must be taken into account. But the before and after certainly cannot be taken into account unless it is placed in the judgment of people who associate with each other and who can therefore also have a corresponding insight into the past and the future. You see, the economic process must be based on the insight of those involved in the economy. This is also evident from these things. It is difficult to weigh up offhand how much the individual factors in the economic process contribute to human life as a whole, insofar as it is material.
From a certain point of view, we can speak of commercial capital, loan capital, and industrial capital in the economic process. Roughly speaking, circulating capital can be broken down into commercial capital, loan capital, and industrial capital. Now, these three things—commercial capital, loan capital, and industrial capital—are involved in the economic process in a wide variety of ways. Now, since such internal economies, as I have discussed today using an example, are scattered throughout the economic process, it is extremely difficult to say, in an economic process taking place within a larger whole, what the quantitative share of loan capital, industrial capital, and commercial capital is in the economic prosperity. However, it is possible to gradually arrive at reliable concepts if these things are considered within a broader horizon.
Let us first look at entire national economies, state economies, as we must say in accordance with modern economic life. Take France, for example. I am only highlighting it as an example. There we have France. Looking at France in its entire global economic context, as it was before the war and as it then manifested itself in its effects during the war, we can observe how loan capital works in the economic process on a large scale. France has actually always had, one might say, a certain tendency to really invest loan capital, that is, to treat loan capital as loan capital. You know that ultimately everything that then spilled over into the political sphere, where one could so clearly see the damage caused by the intertwining of economic and legal life, i.e., political life, played out in relation to France in the lending to both Russia and Turkey. France exported an extraordinary amount of loan capital to Russia and Turkey. Even to Germany, despite the fact that France as a whole was never really on good terms with Germany, French loan capital was exported, for example at the beginning of the construction of the Baghdad Railway, where England had withdrawn; but France had already given loan capital to the people, for example Siemens and Gwinner, who were at the head of the enterprise. So France was essentially a lending country, so that one could see how loan capital is actually entangled in the entire economic process.
I do not want to speak for or against anything, but merely to present the facts objectively. From an external historical phenomenon, you can actually see what interests loan capital actually has. If we turn our attention to private businesses, for example, we will find across the board that private businesspeople are peace-loving people, because they know that if they have lent their capital and war sweeps across the economic landscape, their interest rates will be disrupted. All economists also expect that lenders are peaceful people. That is also the reason why it is always possible to say that France is not to blame for the war. This can be said for the simple reason that, if one wants to prove that France did not want the war, one need only point to the interests of small pensioners, not to the interests of those who drove the country to war. In France, there have always been people in the background who definitely did not want the war. It is precisely this historical fact that can show us on a large scale what is also very much present on a small scale: the lender, i.e., the person who enjoys loan capital, who can give away loan capital, is actually a person who wants to prevent the economy from being disrupted by events that do not belong to the economy itself, including events within the economy itself that cause particularly severe shocks in economic life. Those who have loan capital to lend will love a calm course of events all the more, as they themselves would like to spare themselves the trouble of making judgments and would rather be told: Here and there, something is well invested. In our time, when public judgment is very conceited but, in fact, very limited, we can say that the possibility of lending capital is linked to an extraordinarily strong belief in authority in economic life and in life in general. And that, in turn, clouds economic judgment to an extraordinary degree. People who are labeled in some way or another are easily lent money. Personal credit is readily granted to those who are labeled in some way. That is how the matter is decided. And isn't it true that, depending on whether or not this authoritative principle is cultivated, we also see that either the more personally capable people can intervene productively in economic life, or those who become commercial counselors, for example, not because of their abilities, but because of other connections—which are also supposed to exist. If they can intervene in economic life, things will turn out differently than if one is dependent on the fact that things are conveyed solely through the recognition of personal abilities in purely public judgment. In that case, something intervenes in economic life that is not really comprehensible. In certain circles, it has become all too common recently to use a word whenever people can no longer quite grasp the concepts, and as a result, I have heard the word “imponderables” bandied about far too often in various places recently. I would like to emphasize that I will avoid using this word here and point out how that which is more straightforward branches off into that which we will have to pursue along somewhat more crooked paths; but it is not necessary for the term “imponderables” to be used everywhere, as has been heard ad nauseam in various places recently. Well, that is a brief overview of loan capital.
Moving on to industrial capital, if we want to study industrial capital in its essence – even though this industrial capital has undergone a rather unenlightening fate – we will be able to study the function of industrial capital extremely well, particularly in the upswing of industry in Germany in the decades before the war. This will be particularly easy to do because, under the influence of entrepreneurial spirit, industrial capital has indeed transformed itself directly from loan capital – more so in Germany in the last decades before the war than anywhere else in the world. It is absolutely true, as I mentioned in my very first lecture here, that in England, for example, commercial capital gradually transformed into industrial capital because industrialism in England developed more slowly from commerce than in Germany, where industrialism shot up with tremendous speed, so that in fact what I would call pure industrialism—and it is pure industrialism when it does not transform commercial capital into industrial capital, but rather transforms loan capital into industrial capital—if one wants to study this, one can study it particularly in the German economy.
Well, industrial capital is actually placed between, I would say, two buffers. One buffer is the raw product, the other is the markets. Industrial capital is dependent on finding the best possible sources of raw products and arranging the best possible markets. This is not so easy to study in German industry. German industrialism allows you to study more purely in economic terms how, I would say, industrial capital works within itself; but because the emergence of industrialism in all countries during the 19th century and into the 20th century is significant in economic life, you can actually study this standing between the two buffers everywhere. You just have to look for the right facts of economic life. Then you will find – and as I said, it is good to keep in mind the direction and orientation you need for your concepts in such manageable things – that when you look at smaller economic areas, you have to take extremely difficult paths to find definitions and characteristics for your concepts. You make these paths easier for yourself if you look at economies on a large scale, if you form views on economies on a large scale, as a rule, the concepts of power and the concepts of power sometimes masked in legal concepts are most strongly realized when it comes to exploiting sources of raw materials. We can study this on a large scale, for example in the Boer War, where the main issue was the exploitation of precious metals. This was a real war over raw materials. It always took place under a certain guise, but it was a real war over raw materials. Then you have an example of how economic life unfolds in a political way, playing into politics and power, say in what Belgium did militarily to obtain ivory and rubber from the Congo. There you can see how the exploitation of raw material sources takes place in the national economy. Or take how North America appropriated the Spanish possessions in the West Indies because it sought sources of raw materials for sugar there. So everywhere we can see how the search for raw materials easily drives the purely economic into the political, into the exercise of power. That is one side, the buffer, I would say.
The search for markets is different. And it is easy to prove from history that the search for markets does not lead into political life in the same way. The development of power simply does not evolve in the same way from human nature. A striking example of this can be found in the 19th century, when England conquered the Chinese opium market in the so-called Opium War. But even then, the war was not so easy, and I would say that peaceful politics also had a say in the matter, in that, when the situation became tense, one hundred and forty-one doctors issued an expert opinion stating that opium consumption was no more harmful than tobacco and tea consumption. So politics played a role, peaceful politics; but politics is always difficult to keep out of the picture. You know Clausewitz's statement that war is the continuation of politics by other means. Well, you can always come up with definitions like that: because with this kind of definition, you can also justify the statement that divorce is the continuation of marriage by other means, for example. Yes, if you proceed with this logic, you can put many aspects of life in this or that light, and people will admire it. Strangely enough, everyone notices when I say: Divorce is the continuation of marriage by other means. Everyone notices the story. But when it is proclaimed everywhere that war is the continuation of politics by other means, people do not notice the curious nature of the logic, but admire it. If one applies such logic, particularly in economics, I would like to say methodologically, then one never gets anywhere by establishing such definitions. If we consider this other buffer, the search for markets, then we must admit that human intelligence plays a much greater role in the search for markets, between the poles of cunning, guile, and wise economic leadership. All three types play a very important role in the arrangement of markets, as they were established, particularly by the large economic areas that the states themselves became when politics became linked to the economy; the states themselves have been very active in this regard, both in terms of wise leadership and in terms of cunning, cleverness, shrewdness, and so on. So that for the concepts that one now wants to develop for the individual smaller economic areas concerning the connection between the individual industrial enterprise and its relationship to the sources of raw materials and to the market, one can only really form clear concepts if one considers these things on a large scale.
If one wants to study the function of commercial capital, it is good to study England, preferably during the period when England made its great economic progress through trade, which increased commercial capital, so that England actually entered the new industrialism very gently and gradually. At the time when industrialism was transforming everything, England already had its commercial capital, so that one can study commercial capital in England for earlier times. For more recent times, Marx in particular wanted to study the economic function of industrialism in England; but for earlier times, which preceded the creation of modern industrialism, in the last decades of the 18th century, if one goes back to these, then one finds the function of commercial capital particularly in the economic fortunes of England. And here, of course, it must be said that the essential factor is always competition, whether it is more or less open or hidden, both in the large economy, when it is mainly based on trade, and within trade itself. Certainly, this can be very fair, thanks to the introduction of all kinds of concepts of decency. But it remains competition nonetheless. For what productivity in trade is based on, what allows commercial capital to be treated in the economic process in such a way that it then becomes effective, for example as industrial capital, is based on the fact that commercial capital leads to accumulation, and this accumulation is inconceivable without competition. So that the function of commercial capital can be studied particularly well if one considers the function of competition in economic life.
At the same time, however, these things are also related to historical transformations. It is certainly true that we can say that until about the first third of the 19th century, if we consider the gradually emerging global economy as a whole – before the war it was to a large extent – that until then the most prominent role in economic life was played by the economic processes of trade and industry.
The heyday, I would say, the classical age of loan capital, did not actually begin until the 19th century, and only really towards the second third of the 19th century. And with that, the historical development saw the emergence of those institutions that serve specifically to provide loans, the emergence of banking. So the classical age of loan capital, and with it the development of banking, falls within the last two-thirds of the 19th century and the first decades of the 20th century. With the development of banking, lending developed more and more as what I would call the primary factor in the economic process. But at the same time, something very special became apparent, particularly in lending, namely that large-scale lending, accompanied by the expansion of banking, actually deprived people of control over the circulation of money, so that gradually the process of money circulation became one that – indeed, I can find no other expression for it — impersonal; so that, as I already mentioned in the first lecture, the time has indeed come when money itself is now managing the economy, and people are sometimes up, sometimes down, depending on how they are drawn into this whole stream of the monetary economy. This is happening much more than people actually realize, because the circulation of money has become objectified, impersonal, especially in the last decades of the 19th century. This brings me — and because it is important in economics to assess life as a whole in an unbiased manner, we must look at life as a whole — to a peculiar phenomenon of the 19th century, namely its end, a phenomenon that at first appears to be psychological, but which then plays a major role in economics: that phenomena of life, which are inaugurated by forces that are entirely real forces in the context of life, that these phenomena of life then continue to roll along as if by a kind of social inertia, like a ball continues to roll when I have given it momentum, that the rolling along then takes place even without the original impulses still being active within it. Thus, we had economic impulses within the lending system until the first third of the 19th century. Then these economic impulses began to become purely financial impulses through the banking system. This made the whole thing not only impersonal, but even unnatural; everything was drawn into the self-propelling flow of money. A monetary economy without a natural and personal subject is what was behind the end of the 19th century, which was originally supported by the personal and natural subject.
And it is peculiar that this subjectless economy, this subjectless circulation of money, is accompanied by another phenomenon. This is that states have indeed begun to operate on the basis of economic impulses, for example, attempting to colonize on the basis of economic impulses. Tomorrow we will see what influence this colonization has on economic life; decolonization must also be considered in this context. For example, we can observe very clearly in a real economic process the significance of colonization for England; England has basically never gone beyond colonization, that is, imperialism with objective substance. By imperialism, I mean the incorporation of real economic content. But if you look at German colonization, for example—you only need to examine the colonial balance sheets—you will see that German colonization was initially associated with a completely negative balance. There were only very small areas that had a positive balance. But even in other countries, the tendency to simply expand through colonies gradually crept in. Individual people such as Hilferding, in his book “Finance Capital,” published in Vienna in 1910, called this “imperialism without an object.”
You can therefore speak of these two phenomena as extremely instructive phenomena in recent times: on the one hand, the circulation of money without any natural or personal connection, and on the other hand, objectless imperialism in the large economy. These are two phenomena that have emerged in recent times, as if one had conditioned the other in the overall context. One could say that it is purely psychological at the outset, but it becomes economic as it progresses, because if you have unproductive colonies, you have to pay for that negatively. So it does eventually interfere with economic life.
Well, those are the things we had to discuss today.