World Economy
GA 340
24 July 1922, Dornach
Lecture I
Today I intend a kind of introduction. In tomorrow's lecture we shall begin and try to give a more or less complete picture of the questions of social and political economy which man today must set before himself.
The subject of Economics, as we speak of it today, is in reality a very recent creation. It did not arise until the time when the economic life of modern peoples had become extraordinarily complicated in comparison with earlier conditions. As this Course is intended primarily for students of Political Economy, it is necessary by way of introduction to point out this peculiarity of the economic thinking of today.
After all, we need not go very far back in history to see how much economic life has changed, even during the nineteenth century. You need only consider this one fact: England, for example, already had, during the first half of the century, what was practically the modern form of economic life. There was comparatively little radical change in the economic structure of England in the course of the nineteenth century. The great social questions which arise out of economic questions in modern times were being asked in England as early as the first half of the nineteenth century: and those who wanted to think of social and economic questions in the modern sense could pursue their studies in England at a time when in Germany—for instance—such studies must have remained unfruitful. In England, above all, the conditions of trade and commerce on a large scale had already come into being by the first third of the nineteenth century. Through the great development of trade and commerce in the economic life in England, a foundation was already there in the shape of trade capital. In England there was no need to seek for any other starting-point for modern economic life. They simply had to apply the trade capital resulting from the consolidation of trade and commerce even as early as the first third of the nineteenth century. Starting from this time, everything took place in England with a certain logical consistency; only we must not forget that the whole of this English economic life was only possible on the basis originally given by England's relation to her colonies, especially to India. The whole of the English economic system is unthinkable without the relationship of England to India. In other words, English economic life, with all its facility for evolving large sums of capital, is founded on the fact that there lies in the background a country which is, as it were, virgin economic soil. We must not overlook this fact, especially when we pass from England to Germany.
If you consider the economic life of Germany you will see that in the first third of the nineteenth century it still essentially corresponded to economic customs which had arisen out of the Middle Ages. The economic customs and relationships within Germany in the first third of the nineteenth century were essentially old: consequently the whole tempo of economic life was different in Germany from what it was in England during the first third, or even the first half, of the nineteenth century. In England, during the first half of the century, there was already what we may call a reckoning with quickly changing habits of life. The main character of economic life remained essentially the same: but it was already adaptable to quickly changing habits. In Germany, on the other hand, habits of life were still conservative: economic development could afford to advance at a snail's pace, for it had only to adapt itself to technical conditions, which remained more or less the same over long periods, and to human needs, which were not rapidly changing.
But in this respect a great transformation took place in the second third of the nineteenth century. Then there rapidly took place an approximation to English conditions, a development of the industrial system. In the first half of the nineteenth century Germany had been in all essentials an agrarian country: now it was rapidly transformed into an industrial country, far more rapidly than any other region of the Earth.
But there is an important fact in this connection. We might describe it thus: In England the transition to an industrial condition of life took place instinctively: nobody knew exactly how it happened. It came like an event of Nature. In Germany, it is true, the medieval character still existed in the first third of the nineteenth century. Germany was an agrarian country. But while the outer economic conditions were taking their accustomed course in a way that might almost be called medieval, human thinking was undergoing a fundamental change. It came into the consciousness of men that something altogether different must now arise, that the existing conditions were no longer true to the time. Thus the transformation of economic conditions which arose in Germany in the second third of the nineteenth century took place far more consciously than in England. In Germany people were far more aware of how they entered into modern capitalism: in England people were not aware of it at all. If you read today all the writings and discussions in Germany during that period concerning the transition to industrialism, you will get a remarkable impression, a strange impression, of how the people in Germany were thinking. Why, they actually looked upon it as a real liberation of mankind: they called it Liberalism, Democracy. Nay, more, they regarded it as the very salvation of mankind to get right out of the old connections, the old binding links, the old kind of corporation, and pass over to the fully free position (for so they called it) of the individual within the economic life. Hence in England you will never meet with a theory of Economics such as was developed by the people who received their education in Germany in the height of the period which I have now characterised. Schmoller, Roscher and others derived their views from the heyday of this “Liberalism ” in Political Economy. What they built up was altogether in this sense, and they built it with full consciousness. An Englishman would have thought such theories of Economics stale and boring; he would have said: “One does not trouble to think about such things.” Look at the radical difference between the way in which people in England talked about these things (to mention even a man like Beaconsfield, who was theoretical enough in all conscience) from the way in which Richter or Lasker or even Brentano were speaking in Germany. In Germany, therefore, this second period was entered into with full consciousness.
Then came the third period, the period essentially of the State. It is true, is it not, that as the last third of the nineteenth century drew near, the German State was consolidated purely by means of external power. That which was consolidated was not what the idealists of '48 or even of the 1830's had desired: no, it was the “State” that was consolidated, and moreover by means of sheer force. And this State, by and by, requisitioned the economic life with full consciousness for its own purposes. Thus, in the last third of the nineteenth century, the structure of the economic life was permeated through and through by the very opposite principle to the previous one. In the second third of the century its evolution had been subject to the ideas of “Liberalism.” Now its evolution became altogether subject to the idea of the State. This was what gave the economic life in Germany, as a whole, its stamp. It is true that there were elements of consciousness in the whole process, and yet in another sense the whole thing was quite unconscious.
But the most important thing is this: Through all these developments a radical contrast, an antagonism of principle, was created, not only in thought but in the whole conduct of economic life itself between the English and the Mid-European economy. And, ladies and gentlemen, on this contrast the manner of their economic intercourse depended. The whole economy of the nineteenth century, as it evolved into the twentieth, would be unthinkable without this contrast between the West and Middle Europe. The way in which men sold, the way in which they found a market for their goods, the way in which they manufactured them, all this would be unthinkable without this contrast.
This was the course of development. First the economic and industrial life of England became possible on the basis of her possession of India: next it became possible for the whole economic activity to be extended on the basis of the contrast between the Western and the Mid-European economic life. In effect, the economic life is founded not on what one sees in one's immediate surroundings, but on the great reciprocal relationships in the world at large.
Now it was with this contrast that the world as a whole entered into the state of world-economy and—could not enter! For the world continued to depend on that instinctive element which had evolved from the past, and the existence of which I have just indicated in describing the antithesis between England and Mid-Europe. In the twentieth century, though the world was unaware of the fact, we stood face to face with this situation. The antithesis became more and more immediate, it became deeper and deeper: and we stood before this great question: The economic conditions had evolved out of these antitheses or contrasts and, having done so, they were carrying the contrasts themselves ever more intensely into the future. And yet, if the contrast were to go on for ever increasing, economic intercourse would become impossible. This was the great question of the twentieth century: The contrast had created the economic life; the economic life had in turn enhanced the contrast. The contrast was calling for a solution. The question was: How are these contrasts or antagonisms to be resolved? The further course of history was destined to prove that men were incapable of finding the answer.
It would have been practical to talk in words like these in 1914, in the days of peace. But, in place of a solution, there came the result of failure to find such a world-historic solution. Such was the disease which then set in, seen from the economic aspect.
You must recognise that the possibility of all evolution always depends on contrasts or antitheses in the last resort. I will only mention one example. Through the fact that the English economic life had been consolidated far earlier than the Mid-European, the English were unable to make certain goods at prices as cheap as were possible in Germany. Thus, there arose the great contrast or antagonism of competition, for “Made in Germany” was simply a question of competition. And when the war was over, this question could arise: Now that people have knocked each other's heads in, instead of seeking a solution of existing contrasts, how can we deal with the matter? At this time I could not but believe in the possibility of finding human beings who would understand the contrasts which must be brought forth in another domain. For life depends on contrasts, and can only exist if contrasts are there, interacting with one another. Thus in 1919 one could come to the point of saying: Let us now draw attention to the real contrasts or contra-positions towards which world-historic evolution is tending—those of the economic life, the political life of rights and the spiritual-cultural life—the contra-positions of the threefold social order.
What, after all, was the actual situation when we believed that we must bring the threefold idea into as many human heads as possible? I will only describe it externally today. The important thing would have been to bring the threefold idea into as many heads as possible before the economic consequences ensued which afterwards took place. You must remember when the “Threefold Commonwealth ” was first mentioned, we did not yet stand face to face with the monetary difficulties of today. On the contrary, if the Threefold Commonwealth had been understood at that time, these difficulties could never have occurred. Yet once again we were faced by the inability of human beings to understand such a thing as this in a really practical sense. When we tried to bring the Threefold Commonwealth home to them, people would come and say: “Yes, all that is excellent: we see it perfectly. But, after all, the first thing needful is to counteract the depreciation of the currency.” Ladies and gentlemen, all that one could answer was: “That is contained in the Threefold Order. Set to work with the Threefold Order. That is the only means of counteracting the depreciation of the currency.” People were asking how to do the very thing which the Threefold Commonwealth was meant to do. They did not understand it, however often they declared that they did.
And now the position is such that if we are to speak once more today to people such as you, we can no longer speak in the same forms as we did then. Today another language is necessary: and that is what I want to give you in these present lectures. I want to show you how one must think once more today about these questions, especially if, being young in years, one will still have an opportunity to play one's part in shaping the immediate future.
Thus, on the one hand, we can characterise a certain period—the nineteenth century—in terms of world-historic economic contrasts. But we might also go still farther back and include the time when men first began to think about Political Economy at all. If you take the history of Political Economy you will see that everything before that time took place instinctively. It was only in modern times that there arose that complexity of economic life, in the midst of which men felt it necessary to think about these things.
Now I am speaking, in effect, for students. I am trying to show how students of Economics should find their way into this subject. Let me, therefore, now relate the most essential thing on which it all depends.
You see, the time when men had to begin to think about Political Economy was just the time when they no longer had the thoughts to comprehend such a subject. They simply no longer had the requisite ideas. I will give you an example from Natural Science to indicate that this is so.
We as human beings have our physical bodies, which are heavy just like any other physical bodies. Your physical body will be heavier after a midday meal than before: we could even weigh the difference. That is to say, we partake in the general laws of gravity. But with this gravity, which is the property of all ponderable substances, we could do very little in our human body, we could at most go about the world as automata, certainly not as conscious beings. I have often explained what is essential to any valid concept of these matters. I have often said what man needs for his thinking. The human brain, if we weigh it alone, weighs about 1,400 grammes. If you let the weight of these 1,400 grammes press on the veins and arteries, which are situated at the base of the skull, it would destroy and kill them. You could not live for a single moment if the human brain were pressing downward with its full 1,400 grammes. It is indeed a fortunate thing for man that the principle of Archimedes holds good. I mean that every body loses so much of its weight in water as is the weight of that fluid which it displaces. If this is a heavy body, it loses as much of its weight in water as a body of water of equal size would weigh. The brain swims in the cerebro-spinal fluid, and thereby loses 1,380 grammes: for such is the weight of a body of cerebro-spinal fluid of the size of the human brain. The brain only presses downward on to the base of the skull with a weight of 20 grammes, and this weight it can bear. But if we now ask ourselves: What is the purpose of all this? then we must answer: With a brain which was a mere ponderable mass, we could not think. We do not think with the heavy substance: we think with the buoyancy. The substance must first lose its weight. Only then can we think. We think with that which flies away from the earth.
But we are also conscious in our whole body. How do we become thus conscious? In our whole body there are 25 billions of red blood corpuscles. These 25 billions of red corpuscles are very minute. Nevertheless they are heavy: they are heavy for they contain iron. Every one of these 25 billions of red corpuscles swims in the serum of the blood, and loses weight exactly in accordance with the fluid it displaces. Once again, therefore, in every single blood corpuscle an effect of buoyancy is created—25 billion times. Throughout our body we are conscious by virtue of this upward driving force. Thus we may say: Whatever foodstuffs we consume, they must first, to a very large extent, be divested of their weight: they must be transformed in order that they can serve us. Such is the demand of the living body.
Ladies and gentlemen, to think thus and to regard this way of thinking as essential, is the very thing men ceased to do just at the time when it became necessary to think in terms of Political Economy. Thenceforward they only reckoned with ponderable substances: they no longer thought of the transformation which a substance undergoes in a living organism—as to its weight, for example, through the effect of buoyancy.
And now another thing. If you call to mind your studies of Physics, you will remember the physicist speaks of the “spectrum.” This band of colours is created with the help of the prism: red, orange, yellow, green, blue, indigo, violet. So far (from the red to the violet) the spectrum appears luminous. But, as you know, before the region which shows a luminous effect, what are called the infra-red rays are assumed to exist: and, beyond the violet, the ultra-violet rays. If, therefore, one speaks merely of light, one does not include the totality of the phenomenon: for we must go on to describe how the light is transformed in two opposite directions; we must explain how, beyond the red, light sinks into the element of warmth and, beyond the violet, into chemical effects. In both directions the light, as such, disappears. If, therefore, we give a theory of light alone, we are giving a mere extract. (The current theory of light is in any case not a true one. It is significant that in the very time when mankind had to begin to think consciously of Political Economy, human thinking upon Physics was in such a condition as to result, among other things, in an untrue theory of light).
I have, however, mentioned the matter here with some reason: for there is a valid analogy. Consider for a moment not the economy of peoples, but, let us say, the economy of sparrows or the economy of swallows. They too, after all, have a kind of economy. But this—the economy of the animal kingdom—does not reach far up into the human kingdom, Possibly in the case of the magpie we may indeed speak of a kind of animal capitalism. But what is the essence of animal economics? It is this: Nature provides the products, and the animal as a single creature takes them for him-self. Man does indeed reach down into this animal economy: but he has to emerge from it.
The true human economy may be compared to the part of the spectrum which is visible as light. That which reaches down into Nature would then be comparable with the part of the spectrum which extends into the infra-red. Here, for example, we come into the domain of agriculture, of economic geography and so forth. The science of Economics cannot be sharply defined in this direction: it reaches down into a region which must be grasped by very different methods. That on the one hand.
But on the other hand—just under the influence of the very complicated relations of today—it has gradually come to pass that our economic thinking fails us once more in another direction. Just as light ceases to appear as light, as we go on into the ultraviolet, so does human economic activity cease to be purely economic. I have often characterised how this came about. The phenomenon began only in the nineteenth century. Till then, the economic life was still more or less dependent on the capability and efficiency of the individual human being. A Bank prospered if some individual in it was a thoroughly capable man. Individuals were still of real importance. I have often related, as an amusing example, the story of the ambassador of the King of France who once came to Rothschild. He was trying to raise a loan. Rothschild happened to be in conversation with a leather merchant. When the ambassador of the King of France was announced, he said: “Ask him to wait a little.” The ambassador was terribly upset. Was he to wait, while a leather merchant was in there with Rothschild? When the attendant came out and told him, he simply would not believe his ears. “Go in again and tell Herr Rothschild that I am here as the ambassador of the King of France.” But the attendant brought the same answer again: “Will you kindly wait a little?” Thereupon he himself burst into the inner room: “I am the ambassador of the King of France!” Rothschild answered: “Please sit down: will you take a chair?” “Yes, but I am the ambassador of the King of France!” “Will you take two chairs!”
You see, what took place in the economic life in that time was placed consciously within the sphere of the human personality. But things have changed since then: and now, in the great affairs of economic life, very little indeed depends on the single personality. Human economic working has to a very large extent been drawn into what I am here comparing with the ultra-violet. I refer to the workings of Capital as such. Accumulations of Capital are active as such. Over and above the economic, there lies an ultra-economic life, which is essentially determined by the peculiar power inherent in the actual masses of Capital. If, therefore, we wish to understand the economic life of today, we must regard it thus: It lies in the midst between two regions, of which the one leads downward into Nature and the other upward into Capital. Between them lies the domain which we must comprehend as the economic life properly speaking.
Now from this you will see that men did not even possess the necessary concept to enable them to define the science of Economics and set it in its proper place within the whole domain of knowledge. For, as we shall presently see, it is a curious thing: but this region alone (which we have compared with the infra-red)—this region which does not yet reach up into the sphere of economics properly speaking—this alone is intelligible by the human intellect. We can consider, with ordinary thinking, how to grow oats or barley and so forth: or how best to obtain the raw products in mining. That is all that we can really think about with the intellect which we have grown accustomed to apply in the science of modern time.
This is a fact of immense significance. Think back for a moment to what I have just indicated as the concept which we need in science. We consume heavy substances as food. That they can be of use to us, depends upon the fact that they continually lose weight within us. That is to say, within the body they are totally transformed. But that is not all. They are changed in a different way in each organ: it is a different change in the liver from that in the brain or in the lung. The organism is differentiated and the conditions are different for each substance in each single organ. We have a perpetual change of quality along with the change from organ to organ.
Now, it is approximately the same when, within a given economic domain, we speak of the value of a commodity. It is nonsense to define some substance as carbon, for example, and then to ask: How does it behave inside the human body? The carbon, even as regards its weight, becomes something altogether different from what it is here or there in the outer world. Likewise, we cannot simply ask: What is the value of a commodity? The value is different according as the commodity is lying in a shop, or is transported to this place or that.
Thus, our ideas in Economics must be altogether mobile. We must rid ourselves of the habit of constructing concepts capable of definition once and for all. We must realise that we are dealing with a living process, and must transform our concepts with the process. But what the economists have tried to do is to grasp such things as Value, Price, Production, Consumption and so forth with ideas such as they had in ordinary science. And these were of no use.
Fundamentally speaking, therefore, we have not yet attained a true science of Economics. With the concepts to which we have grown accustomed hitherto, we cannot answer the question, for instance: What is Value? Or, what is Price? Whatever has Value must be considered as being in perpetual circulation: like-wise we must consider the Price, corresponding to a Value, as something in perpetual circulation. If you simply ask: What are the physical properties of carbon? you will still know absolutely nothing of what goes on in the lung, for example, although carbon is also present in the lung. For its whole configuration becomes quite different in the lung. In the same way, iron, when you find it in the mine, is something altogether different from what it is in the economic process. Economics is concerned with something quite different from the mere fact that it “is” iron. It is with these unstable, constantly changing factors that we must reckon.
Forty-five years ago, I came into a certain family. They showed me a picture. I think it had been lying up in a loft for about fifty years. So long as it lay there, and no one was there who knew any more about it than that it was the kind of thing one throws away in a corner of the loft, it had no value in the economic process. Once its value had been recognised, it was worth 30.000 gulden—quite a large sum of money in those days. What did the value depend on in this case? Purely and simply on the opinion men formed of the picture. The picture had not been removed from its place, only men had arrived at different thoughts about it. And so in no case does it depend on what a thing immediately “is.” The conceptions of Economics are the very ones which you can never evolve by reference to the mere external reality. No, you must always evolve them by reference to the economic process as a whole: and within this process each thing is perpetually changing. Therefore we must speak of the economic process of circulation before we can arrive at such things as Value, Price and so forth. In the economic theories of today, you will observe that they generally begin with definitions of Value and Price. That is quite wrong. The first thing needful is to describe the economic process. Only then do those things emerge with which the theorists of today begin.
Now, in the year 1919, when everything had been destroyed, one might have thought that people would realise the need to begin with something fresh. Alas, it was not the case. The small number of people who did believe that there must be a new beginning, very soon fell into the comfortable reflection: “After all, there is nothing to be done.” Meanwhile, the great calamity was taking place: the devaluation of money in the Eastern and Middle countries of Europe, and with it a complete revolution in the social strata; for it goes without saying that with each progressive devaluation of money, those who live by what I have here compared to the ultra-violet must be impoverished. And this is happening to-day, far more perhaps than people are yet aware. And it will happen, more and more completely. Here, above all, we are directed to the idea of the living, social organism. For it is evident that this devaluation of money is determined by the old State frontiers and limitations. The old State frontiers and limitations are interfering with the economic process. The latter must indeed be understood, but we must first gain an understanding of the social organism. Yet all the systems of Political Economy—from Adam Smith to the most modern—reckon, after all, with small isolated regions as if they were complete social organisms. They do not realise that, even if one is only using an analogy, the analogy must be correct. Have you ever seen an elaborate or full-grown organism, such as the human being, for instance, in this drawing—and immediately beside it a second one, and here a third, and so forth? (see Diagram 1) They would look quite pretty—these human organisms, sticking to one another in this way: and yet with elaborate and full-grown organisms there is no such thing. But with the separate States and Countries, this is the case. Living organisms require an empty space around them—empty space between them and other living organisms. You could at most compare the single States with the cells of the organism. It is only the whole Earth which, as a body economic, can truly be compared with a living organism. This ought surely to be taken into account. It is quite palpable, ever since we have had a world-economy, that the single States or Countries are at most to be compared with cells.
The whole Earth, considered as an economic organism, is the social organism.
Yet this is nowhere being taken into account. It is precisely owing to this error that the whole science of Political Economy has grown so remote from reality. People will seek to establish principles that are only to apply to certain individual cells. Hence, if you study French political economy, you will find it differently constituted from English or German or other political economies. But as economists, what we really need is an understanding of the social organism in its totality.
So much for today by way of introduction.

Erster Vortrag
Zunächst möchte ich heute mit einer Art Einleitung beginnen und dann morgen übergehen zu demjenigen, was in gewisser Beziehung ein Ganzes ergeben soll über nationalökonomische, über sozialökonomische Fragen, die sich in der Gegenwart der Mensch stellen muß.
Die Nationalökonomie, wie man nun einmal in der Gegenwart von ihr spricht, sie ist eigentlich erst eine neuere Schöpfung. Sie ist entstanden im Grunde genommen erst in der Zeit, als das wirtschaftliche Leben der neueren Völker außerordentlich kompliziert geworden ist gegenüber früheren wirtschaftlichen Verhältnissen. Und da wir hier diesen Kursus so gestalten wollen, wie er hauptsächlich für den Studenten der Nationalökonomie eben gestaltet werden soll, so muß ja einleitend gerade auch auf diese besondere Eigentümlichkeit des nationalökonomischen Denkens von heute hingewiesen werden.
Wir brauchen uns ja schließlich gar nicht einmal sehr weit in der Geschichte zurückzubegeben, so werden wir schon sehen, wie das wirtschaftliche Leben auch, sagen wir, nur während des 19. Jahrhunderts selbst sich verändert hat gegenüber früheren Verhältnissen. Beachten Sie nur einmal die eine Tatsache, daß in gewissem Sinn zum Beispiel England im wesentlichen wirtschaftlich neuzeitlich gestaltet war schon in der ersten Hälfte des 19. Jahrhunderts, so daß eigentlich verhältnismäßig wenig in der wirtschaftlichen Struktur in England sich radikal verändert hat im Laufe des 19. Jahrhunderts. Die großen Fragen, die sich in der neueren Zeit in sozialer Hinsicht an die wirtschaftlichen Fragen anschließen, waren in England schon da in der ersten Hälfte des 19. Jahrhunderts, und schon damals konnten diejenigen Menschen, welche darauf ausgingen, im modernen Sinn das Sozialökonomische zu denken, ihre Studien in England machen, während solche Studien dazumal noch, sagen wir, in Deutschland hätten unfruchtbar bleiben müssen. In England hatten sich vor allen Dingen die großen Handelsverhältnisse bereits herausgebildet bis in das erste Drittel des 19. Jahrhunderts, und es war innerhalb der englischen Volkswirtschaft durch diese Herausbildung der Struktur des Handelswesens geschaffen eine Grundlage in dem Handelskapital. Man hatte in England nicht notwendig, für die neuere Wirtschaft an einen anderen Ausgangspunkt anzuknüpfen als an das, was sich als Handelskapital ergeben hatte aus den konsolidierten Handelsverhältnissen, die eben schon bestanden, sogar schon im ersten Drittel des 19. Jahrhunderts. An diese Zeit anknüpfend, hat sich dann für England alles mit einer gewissen Folgerichtigkeit ergeben. Nur dürfen wir nicht vergessen, daß die ganze englische Wirtschaft nur möglich war auf der Grundlage, die sich aus dem Verhältnis Englands zu den Kolonien ergeben hatte, namentlich zu Indien. Die ganze englische Volkswirtschaft ist nicht denkbar ohne das Verhältnis Englands zu Indien. Das heißt aber mit anderen Worten: Diese englische Volkswirtschaft mit ihrer Möglichkeit, große Kapitalien herauszubilden, ist aufgebaut dar‚ auf, daß ein gewissermaßen wirtschaftlich jungfräuliches Land im Hintergrund liegt. Das dürfen wir nicht übersehen, namentlich nicht, wenn wir jetzt herübersehen von der englischen Volkswirtschaft in die deutsche herein.
Verfolgen Sie diese, so werden Sie sehen, daß sie zum Beispiel im ersten Drittel des 19. Jahrhunderts noch wesentlich so ist, daß sie entspricht den wirtschaftlichen Gewohnheiten, die sich noch aus dem Mittelalter heraus ergeben haben. Die wirtschaftlichen Gewohnheiten und wirtschaftlichen Zusammenhänge sind innerhalb Deutschlands im ersten Drittel des 19. Jahrhunderts durchaus alte. Damit war das ganze Tempo des wirtschaftlichen Lebens in Deutschland ein anderes als zum Beispiel in England im ersten Drittel, ja in der ersten Hälfte des 19. Jahrhunderts. In England spielte sich dasjenige schon ab in dieser ersten Jahrhunderthälfte, was man nennen kann das Rechnen mit rasch wechselnden Lebensgewohnheiten. Es bleibt der allgemeine Zug des wirtschaftlichen Lebens im wesentlichen derselbe, aber er ist schon berechnet auf rasch wechselnde Gewohnheiten. In Deutschland sind diese selber noch konservativ. Das wirtschaftliche Leben kann noch einen Schneckengang gehen, kannnochangepaßtseindemUmstand, daß die Verhältnisse in technischer Beziehung durch lange Zeit hindurch ungefähr gleich bleiben, daß auch die Bedürfnisse sich nicht rasch ändern.
Darin ist aber ein Umschwung eingetreten im zweiten Drittel des 19. Jahrhunderts. Da entwickelte sich rasch heraus eine Anähnlichung an die englischen Verhältnisse unter der Ausbildung des industriellen Wesens. Deutschland war in der ersten Hälfte des 19. Jahrhunderts im wesentlichen ein Agrarland, es wurde aber rasch umgewandelt in ein Industrieland, viel rascher umgewandelt als irgendein anderes Gebiet der Erde.
Aber das war mit etwas anderem noch verknüpft. Man möchte sagen: In England hat sich der Übergang zu einer industriellen Auffassung der Volkswirtschaft instinktiv herausgebildet; man wußte eigentlich gar nicht wie. Er ist gekommen wie ein Naturereignis. In Deutschland war zwar das Mittelalterliche im ersten Drittel des 19. Jahrhunderts vorhanden — Deutschland war ein Agrarstaat; aber während die äußeren wirtschaftlichen Verhältnisse in der Weise verliefen, daß man sie fast noch mittelalterlich nennen könnte, hat sich das menschliche Denken gründlich geändert. Ins Bewußtsein der Menschen ist eingezogen, daß da etwas anderes kommen muß, daß das eigentlich nicht mehr zeitgemäß ist, was vorhanden ist; und so hat sich das, was sich als Umbildung der wirtschaftlichen Verhältnisse im zweiten Drittel des 19. Jahrhunderts in Deutschland ergeben hat, viel bewußter vollzogen als in England. Die Leute haben viel mehr gewußt in Deutschland - in England wußte man es gar nicht -, wie man hineingekommen ist in den modernen Kapitalismus. Würden Sie heute das, was man dazumal, ich möchte sagen, auseinandergesetzt hat, gesprochen hat über das Hineingehen in den Industrialismus, würden Sie das lesen, so würden Sie die Vorstellung bekommen: Ja, es ist merkwürdig, wie da die Leute in Deutschland gedacht haben. — Die Leute haben es geradezu als eine volle Menschenbefreiung angesehen — man hat das Liberalismus genannt, Demokratie genannt -, die Leute haben das geradezu angesehen wie das Heil der Menschheit, nun herauszukommen aus alten Bindungen, aus dem alten Korporationswesen, und zu der völlig freien Stellung - wie man es nannte — des Menschen im wirtschaftlichen Leben überzugehen. Wir erblicken deshalb in England niemals eine Theorie über die Volkswirtschaft, wie sie etwa ausgebildet haben Leute, die ihre Bildung aus der Hochblüte dieser Zeit gezogen haben, die ich charakterisiert habe. Schmoller, Roscher und andere haben ihre Ansichten gezogen aus der Hochblüte dieser liberalistischen Volkswirtschaft. Mit vollem Bewußtsein haben sie aufgebaut, was durchaus in diesem Sinne aufgebaut war. Solch eine Volkswirtschaftslehre würde der Engländer fade gefunden haben. Man denkt doch über solche Dinge nicht nach, würde er gesagt haben. Daher betrachten Sie nur den radikalen Unterschied, wenn man in England - ich will bloß nehmen selbst solche Leute, die schon theoretisch genug waren, wie Beaconsfield-, wenn sie gesprochen haben über solche Fragen, oder wenn in Deutschland gesprochen haben Richter, Lasker oder selbst Brentano. In Deutschland also ist man mit Bewußtsein in diese zweite Periode eingezogen.
Dann kam die dritte Periode, die eigentliche staatliche Periode. Nicht wahr, als das letzte Drittel des 19. Jahrhunderts heranrückte, da konsolidierte sich der deutsche Staat im Grunde genommen durch reine Machtmittel. Es konsolidierte sich nicht dasjenige, was die Idealisten von den achtundvierziger oder auch schon von den dreißiger Jahren an wollten, sondern da konsolidierte sich der Staat durch reine Machtmittel. Dieser Staat nahm auch nach und nach mit vollem Bewußtsein das wirtschaftliche Leben für sich in Anspruch, so daß das wirtschaftliche Leben in seiner Struktur ganz durchsetzt wurde im letzten Drittel des 19. Jahrhunderts von dem entgegengesetzten Prinzip als früher. Im zweiten Drittel hatte es sich entwickelt unter den liberalistischen Anschauungen, jetzt entwickelte es sich ganz unter den Anschauungen des Staatsprinzips. Das gab dem Wirtschaftsleben in Deutschland seine Gesamtsignatur; und zwar waren Bewußtseinselemente in dieser ganzen Entwickelung drinnen. Und das Ganze war doch wiederum unbewußt.
Das Wichtigste war nun, daß ja dadurch, nicht etwa bloß im Denken, sondern im ganzen Wirtschaften selber, ein radikaler Gegensatz geschaffen war zwischen dem, was englische Wirtschaft war, und dem, was nun mitteleuropäische Wirtschaft war. Ja, aber auf diesem Gegensatz beruhte es, wie man miteinander wirtschaftete. Die ganze Wirtschaft des 19. Jahrhunderts, wie sie sich entwickelte ins 20. Jahrhundert, wäre nicht denkbar gewesen ohne diesen Gegensatz des Westens und der europäischen Mitte: daß man so, wie man verkaufte, verkaufte, so, wie man Waren anbrachte, sie anbrachte, wie man sie fabrizierte, sie fabrizierte.
Und so hat sich allmählich herausgebildet die Möglichkeit der englischen Wirtschaft auf Grundlage des Besitzes von Indien, und jetzt die Möglichkeit der Erweiterung des Wirtschaftens auf Grundlage des Gegensatzes zwischen westlicher und mitteleuropäischer Wirtschaft. Das Wirtschaftsleben beruht ja nicht auf demjenigen, was man so sieht in seiner allernächsten Umgebung, sondern auf den großen gegenseitigen Verhältnissen in der Welt draußen.
Mit diesem Gegensatz nun trat eben die Welt überhaupt in die Weltwirtschaft dann ein und - konnte in die Weltwirtschaft nicht hinein. Denn sie beruhte eigentlich auf den instinktiven Elementen, die sich heraufentwickelt hatten und die ich eben angedeutet habe mit dem Gegensatz zwischen England und Mitteleuropa. Im 20. Jahrhundert stand man eigentlich - ohne daß die Welt es wußte, sie bemerkte nichts davon - davor, daß dieser Gegensatz immer aktueller und aktueller, immer tiefer und tiefer wurde. Der Gegensatz wurde immer aktueller und aktueller, immer tiefer und tiefer, und man stand vor der großen Frage: Die wirtschaftlichen Verhältnisse sind aus diesen Gegensätzen heraus entwickelt, sie tragen diese Gegensätze immer mehr und mehr in die Zukunft hinein; aber zu gleicher Zeit, wenn die Gegensätze immer größer und größer wurden, konnte man nicht miteinander wirtschaften. Das war die große Frage des 20. Jahrhunderts — der Gegensatz hatte die Wirtschaft geschaffen, die Wirtschaft hatte den Gegensatz vergrößert, der Gegensatz bedurfte einer Lösung -, die Frage war dann: Wie löst man die Gegensätze? - Nun, die geschichtliche Entwickelung hat gezeigt, daß die Menschen nicht imstande waren, die Frage zu lösen.
So wie ich jetzt gesprochen habe, hätte man sprechen können 1914 im Frieden. Dann ist statt einer Lösung gekommen das Ergebnis der Unfähigkeit, eine welthistorische Lösung zu finden. Das ist die Krankheit, die da eintrat, wenn man die Sache von der wirtschaftlichen Seite anschaut.
Nun, auf Gegensätzen beruht im Grunde genommen die Möglichkeit aller Entwickelung. Ich will nur einen solchen Gegensatz nennen: Dadurch, daß die englische Wirtschaft in viel früherer Zeit konsolidiert worden war als die mitteleuropäische, waren die Engländer nicht fähig, für gewisse Waren so billige Preise zu machen, wie das in Deutschland der Fall war, so daß der große Gegensatz der Konkurrenz entstand; denn das «Made in Germany» war eine Frage der Konkurrenz. Und als dann der Krieg vorbei war, da konnte die Frage entstehen: Ja, wie kann man jetzt, nachdem sich die Menschen zunächst die Köpfe eingeschlagen hatten, statt nach einer Lösung der Gegensätze zu suchen, wie kann man jetzt mit den Dingen fertig werden? Da mußte ich glauben, daß die Menschen zunächst gefunden werden müßten, die nun das verstehen sollten, was auf einem anderen Gebiet als Gegensätze geschaffen werden muß; denn das Leben beruht auf Gegensätzen und kann nur existieren, wenn Gegensätze da sind, die miteinander spielen. Und so konnte man 1919 darauf kommen, zu sagen: Also weise man auf die Gegensätze hin, nach denen eigentlich die welthistorische Entwickelung tendiert, auf die Gegensätze des Wirtschaftlichen, Rechtlich-Politischen und Geistig-Kulturellen, auf die Gegensätze der Dreigliederung.
Was war im Grunde genommen das Richtige an der Sache, daß man damals dachte, man müsse die Dreigliederung in möglichst viele Köpfe hineinbringen? Ich will heute nur äußerlich charakterisieren: das Wichtigste war, daß man zunächst die Dreigliederung in möglichst viele Köpfe hineingebracht hätte, bevor die wirtschaftlichen Folgen aufgetreten sind, die seither eingetreten sind. Sie müssen bedenken: als die Dreigliederung zuerst genannt worden ist, standen wir noch nicht vor den Valutaschwierigkeiten von heute; im Gegenteil, wäre damals die Dreigliederung verstanden worden, so hätten sie nie kommen können. Aber wiederum stand man vor der Unmöglichkeit, daß die Menschen so etwas in wirklich praktischem Sinn verstanden. Man versuchte damals, die Dreigliederung verständlich zu machen, und dann fragten einen die Leute: Ja, das wäre alles schön, wir sehen es auch ein; aber das erste ist ja doch, daß wir dem Niedergang der Valuta entgegenarbeiten. — Ja man konnte den Leuten nur sagen: Das steckt ja in der Dreigliederung! Bequemt euch zu der Dreigliederung, sie ist das einzige Mittel, um gegen den Valutaniedergang zu arbeiten!Die Leute fragten gerade, wie man das macht, was doch gerade die Dreigliederung hätte treffen sollen. Sie verstanden also die Dreigliederung nicht, wenn sie das auch immer behaupteten.
Und so liegt heute die Sache so, daß man sagen muß: Spricht man heute wiederum zu Persönlichkeiten, wie Sie es sind, so kann man nicht mehr in denselben Formen sprechen wie dazumal, sondern heute ist eine andere Sprache notwendig. Und das ist das, was ich Ihnen jetzt in diesen Vorträgen hier geben möchte. Ich möchte Ihnen zeigen, wie man heute nun wiederum über die Fragen zu denken hat, namentlich, wenn man jung ist und man noch mitwirken kann an dem, was sich einmal in den nächsten Zeiten gestalten muß.
So kann man auf der einen Seite eine Zeit charakterisieren, das 19. Jahrhundert, in weltgeschichtlichen, wirtschaftlichen Gegensätzen. Man könnte aber auch weiter zurückgehen und man umfaßt dann die Zeit, in der die Menschen angefangen haben über Nationalökonomie zu denken. Sie können, wenn Sie die Geschichte der Nationalökonomie nehmen, sehen: früher ging alles instinktiv. Eigentlich kommt erst in der neueren Zeit jene Kompliziertheit des Wirtschaftslebens herauf, in der man es für notwendig fühlt, über die Dinge zu denken.
Nun spreche ich eben eigentlich für Studenten, spreche eigentlich so, wie Studenten sich hineinfinden sollen in die Nationalökonomie. Deshalb möchte ich jetzt das Wesentlichste, worauf es heute ankommt, sagen. Die Zeit, in der man über Nationalökonomie nachdenken sollte, war schon die Zeit, wo man nicht mehr die Gedanken hatte, um solch ein Gebiet zu umfassen, wie das volkswirtschaftliche Gebiet es ist. Man hatte einfach nicht mehr die Ideen dazu. Ich will Ihnen durch Heranziehen eines Beispieles aus der Naturwissenschaft zeigen, daß das so ist.
Die Sache ist so: Wir haben als Menschen unseren physischen Leib, der schwer ist, wie andere physische Körper schwer sind. Er wird schwerer nach einem Mittagsmahl sein, als er vor einem Mittagsmahl ist. Man könnte ihn sogar abwiegen. Das heißt, wir nehmen an der allgemeinen Schwere teil. Aber mit dieser Schwere, die die Eigenschaft alles ponderablen Stofflichen ist, könnten wir im menschlichen Leibe nicht viel anfangen; wir könnten höchstens als Automaten in der Welt herumgehen, nicht aber als bewußte Wesen. Ich habe es schon öfter gesagt, was man braucht, um sich Begriffe zu bilden, die einen Wert haben, habe öfter gesagt, was notwendig ist für den Men schen zum Denken. Das menschliche Gehirn ist ungefähr 1400 Gramm schwer, wenn man es für sich wiegt. Wenn Sie diese 1400 Gramm auf die Adern drücken lassen, die da an der Schädeldecke unten sind, dann quetscht es diese tot. Sie könnten keinen Augenblick leben, wenn das menschliche Gehirn so wäre, daß es mit seinen ganzen 1400 Gramm daraufdrückte. Es ist schon ein Glück für den Menschen, daß das archimedische Prinzip besteht, daß jeder Körper im Wasser so viel an Gewicht verliert, als das Gewicht der Flüssigkeit beträgt, die er verdrängt. Wenn Sie also im Wasser einen schweren Körper haben, so verliert dieser ebensoviel von seinem Gewicht, als ein gleich großer Wasserkörper schwer ist. Das Gehirn schwimmt im Gehirnwasser und verliert dabei 1380 Gramm; denn so viel ist das Gewicht des Wasserkörpers, der gleich groß ist wie das menschliche Gehirn. Das Gehirn drückt nur mit 20 Gramm auf die Grundlage, und das kann diese Grundlage ertragen. Aber wenn wir uns jetzt fragen: Wozu ist denn das? - dann müssen wir sagen: Mit einem Gehirn, das bloß ponderable Masse ist, könnten wir nicht denken. Wir denken nicht mit dem, was schwerer Stoff ist, sondern wir denken mit dem Auftrieb. Der Stoff muß erst seine Schwere verlieren, dann können wir denken. Wir denken mit dem, was wegfliegt von der Erde.
Wir sind uns aber im ganzen Körper bewußt. Wodurch werden wir uns denn in unserem ganzen Körper bewußt? In unserem ganzen Körper sind fünfundzwanzig Billionen roter Blutkörperchen. Diese fünfundzwanzig Billionen roter Blutkörperchen sind sehr klein; sie sind aber doch schwer, sind dadurch schwer, daß sie Eisen enthalten. Jedes dieser fünfundzwanzig Billionen roterBlutkörperchenschwimmt, schwimmt im Blutserum und verliert so viel an Gewicht, als es verdrängt an Flüssigkeit. So daß wiederum in jedem einzelnen Blutkörperchen ein Auftrieb erzeugt wird, fünfundzwanzig Billionen Mal also erzeugt wird. In unserem ganzen Körper sind wir bewußt durch das, was heraufstößt. So daß wir sagen können: Wenn wir Nahrungsmittel zu uns nehmen, so müssen diese zuerst zum großen Teil entschwert werden, umgewandelt werden, damit sie uns dienen können. Das ist die Anforderung des Organismus.
So zu denken und das als etwas Maßgebendes anzusehen, hat man verlernt in der Zeit, wo es notwendig geworden ist, nationalökonomisch zu denken. Von da ab rechnete man nur mit den ponderablen Stoffen, dachte man nicht daran, welche Umwandlung zum Beispiel in einem Organismus ein Stoff hinsichtlich seiner Schwere erfährt, indem er einen Auftrieb hat.
Aber noch etwas anderes. Wenn Sie sich an Ihre physikalischen Studien heute noch erinnern, so werden Sie ja wissen, man redet in der Physik vom Spektrum. Man erzeugt durch das Prisma dieses Farbenband: Rot, Orange, Gelb, Grün, Blau, Indigo, Violett. So weit, vom Roten bis zum Violetten, erscheint das Spektrum beleuchtet. Sie wissen aber, daß angenommen werden vor dem Gebiet, das Lichtwirkungen hat, die sogenannten ultraroten Strahlen und jenseits des Violetten die ultravioletten Strahlen. Wenn also einer bloß vom Licht redet, so umfaßt er nicht das Ganze dieser Erscheinung; er muß davon reden, wie das Licht nach zwei Seiten hin polarisch umgeändert wird; er muß davon reden, daß außerhalb des Rot das Licht in die Wärme hinein versinkt und außerhalb des Violett in die chemischen Wirkungen und eigentlich verschwindet als Licht. Wenn also einer eine bloße Lichtlehre gibt, so gibt er einen bloßen Ausschnitt; wir geben aber noch dazu eine falsche Lichtlehre. In derselben Zeit, in der man hätte anfangen sollen, über Nationalökonomie zu denken, war die Physik, das physikalische Denken in einem solchen Zustand, daß eine falsche Lichtlehre herausgekommen ist.
Dieses habe ich Ihnen angeführt aus dem Grunde, weil hier eine gültige Analogie besteht. Bitte, betrachten Sie die - nun nicht Volkswirtschaft, sondern die Spatzenwirtschaft oder Schwalbenwirtschaft! Das ist ja auch eine Art von Wirtschaft; aber diese Wirtschaft im Tierreich, die reicht nicht weit in das Menschentreich herauf. Beim Hamster können wir ja sogar von einem Tierkapitalismus reden. Das Wesentliche der Tierwirtschaft besteht darin, daß die Natur die Produkte darbietet und sich das Tier als Einzelwesen diese nimmt. Der Mensch ragt schon noch hinein in diese tierische Wirtschaft, aber er muß heraus aus ihr.
Diejenige Wirtschaft, von der man zunächst eigentlich als einer menschlichen Wirtschaft reden kann, ist zu vergleichen mit dem, was im Spektrum als Licht sichtbar ist, während wir das, was noch in die Natur hineinragt, vergleichen müssen mit dem, was ins Ultrarote hineinragt. Da ragen wir hinein zum Beispiel in das Gebiet der Landwirtschaft, ragen hinein in das Gebiet der wirtschaftlichen Geographie und so weiter. Die Wirtschaftslehre können wir nach dieser Richtung nicht fest begrenzen. Die Wirtschaftslehre ragt hinein in ein Gebiet, das auf ganz andere Weise erfaßt werden muß. Das auf der einen Seite.
Auf der andern Seite aber ist man gerade unter unseren komplizierteren Wirtschaftsverhältnissen allmählich dazu gekommen, daß eigentlich wiederum das wirtschaftliche Denken dem Menschen entfällt. Geradeso wie das Licht aufhört, gegen das Ultraviolette hinein als Licht zu erscheinen, so hört das menschliche Wirken im Wirtschaften auf, rein wirtschaftlich zu sein. Ich habe das öfters charakterisiert, wie sich das zugetragen hat. Diese Erscheinung beginnt eigentlich erst im 19. Jahrhundert. Bis dorthin ist das Wirtschaftsleben noch ziemlich abhängig von der einzelnen menschlichen Tüchtigkeit. Eine Bank gedieh, wenn ein einzelner an der Bank tüchtig war. Die einzelnen bedeuteten noch etwas. Ich habe öfters das niedliche Beispiel erzählt, wie einmal zu Rothschild gekommen ist ein abgesandter Minister des Königs von Frankreich. Er wollte dort einen Pump anlegen. Rothschild verhandelte gerade mit einem Lederhändler und sagte, als ihm gemeldet wurde der Abgesandte des Königs von Frankreich: Nun, er solle ein bißchen warten. - Nun war der Mann furchtbar bedrückt. Er solle warten, drinnen ist ein Lederhändler! Als der Diener herauskam und das sagte, glaubte er es ihm gar nicht. Ja, sagen Sie drinnen dem Herrn Rothschild, daß ich als Abgesandter des Königs von Frankreich komme! - Der Diener brachte die Antwort: Ja, Sie sollen warten. Da springt er hinein und sagt: Ich bin der Abgesandte des Königs von Frankreich. — Rothschild antwortet: Bitte, setzen Sie sich, nehmen Sie sich einen Stuhl! - Ja, ich bin der Abgesandte des Königs von Frankreich! - Bitte, nehmen Sie sich zwei Stühle!
Ja, es war das, was damals geschah im Wirtschaftsleben, bewußt in die menschliche Persönlichkeit gestellt. Aber es ist anders geworden. Es ist so geworden, daß heute von der einzelnen Persönlichkeit im Großen des Wirtschaftslebens ungemein wenig abhängt. Das menschliche wirtschaftliche Wirken ist schon sehr stark hineingegangen in dieses, was ich vergleichen möchte mit dem Ultraviolett. Und das ist dasjenige, was als Kapital als solches arbeitet. Die Kapitalmassen arbeiten als solche. Es liegt über dem wirtschaftlichen ein ultrawirtschaftliches Leben, was im wesentlichen bedingt ist von der Eigenkraft der Kapitalmassen, so daß wir sagen müssen: Wollen wir heute wirklich das wirtschaftliche Leben begreifen, so müssen wir es so ansehen, daß es in der Mitte liegt zwischen zwei Gebieten, wovon das eine in die Natur hinunter und das andere in das Kapital hinauf führt. Und dazwischen liegt das, was wir als das eigentliche wirtschaftliche Leben zu erfassen haben.
Aber daraus geht ja hervor, daß man nicht einmal den Begriff hatte, um die Wirtschaftslehre selbst richtig einzugrenzen, richtig hineinzustellen in das gesamte Wissen. Denn wir werden es sehen: kurioserweise ist nur dieses Gebiet, was noch nicht in das Wirtschaften eigentlich hineingeht, was sich mit dem Ultraroten vergleichen läßt, nur dieses ist mit dem menschlichen Verstand zu fassen. Man kann nachdenken wie über andere Prozesse: Wie man Hafer baut, wie man Gerste baut und so weiter, wie man die Rohprodukte am besten zutage fördert im Bergbau. Man kann im Grunde genommen nur über dieses mit dem Verstand richtig denken, den man gewohnt worden ist in der Wissenschaft der neueren Zeit anzuwenden.
Das ist von einer immensen Bedeutung! Denn denken Sie nur doch zurück an das, was ich gegeben habe als den Begriff, den man braucht in der Wissenschaft. Wir genießen als Nahrungsmittel schwere Stoffe. Daß sie uns dienen können, beruht darauf, daß sie fortwährend ihr Gewicht verlieren in uns, daß sie sich also total umändern. Das geht aber so weit, daß sie sich in jedem Organ anders umändern. In der Leber ist eine andere Umänderung als im Gehirn oder in der Lunge. Der Organismus ist differenziert und die Verhältnisse werden für jeden Stoff in jedem Organ anders. Wir haben eine fortwährende Änderung der Qualität in der Änderung der Organe.
So ist es ungefähr, wenn wir reden innerhalb eines volkswirtschaftlichen Ganzen, sagen wir von dem Wert einer Ware. Geradeso wie es Unsinn ist, irgendeinen Stoff, sagen wir als Kohlenstoff zu definieren und dann zu fragen: Wie benimmt er sich im menschlichen Körper? der Kohlenstoff wird bis auf seine Ponderabilität etwas ganz anderes, als er da oder dort in der Außenwelt ist - ebensowenig kann man nach dem Wert einer Ware fragen. Dieser. ist ein anderer, ob die Ware in einem Laden liegt oder ob sie da- oder dorthin transportiert ist.
Die Ideen der Volkswirtschaft müssen ganz beweglich sein. Wir müssen uns abgewöhnen, solche Begriffe zu konstruieren, die man definieren kann. Es muß uns klar sein, daß wir es mit einem lebendigen Prozeß zu tun haben und daß wir die Begriffe im lebendigen Prozeß umformen müssen. Nun versuchte man aber gerade, Wert, Preis, Produktion, Konsumtion und so weiter mit den Ideen zu erfassen, die man hatte. Aber die taugten nichts. Daher haben wir im Grunde eine Volkswirtschaftslehre nicht erringen können. Wir können nicht mit den Begriffen, die wir gewohnt worden sind, zum Beispiel die Frage: Was ist Wert, was ist Preis? — beantworten; denn wir müssen das, was Wert hat, fortwährend in Zirkulation betrachten, wir müssen den Preis, der einem Wert entspricht, in fortwährender Zirkulation betrachten. Und sehen Sie, wenn Sie fragen nach der einfachen physikalischen Eigenschaft des Kohlenstofles, so werden Sie gar nichts wissen von dem, was zum Beispiel in der Lunge vorgeht, obwohl er auch in der Lunge ist, weil die ganze Konfiguration eben etwas ganz anderes wird in der Lunge. So ist das Eisen, wenn Sie es im Bergwerk finden, etwas ganz anderes als im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß. Die Volkswirtschaft geht auf etwas ganz anderes, als daß es Eisen «ist». Aber mit solch labilen Faktoren muß gerechnet werden.
Ich kam einmal in eine Familie vor etwa fünfundvierzig Jahren. Da zeigte man mir ein Bild. Das Bild, das lag, ich glaube, dreißig Jahre auf dem Boden. Solange es da gelegen hat und kein Mensch da war, der etwas anderes von dem Bild gewußt hat, als daß es so etwas ist, das in eine Ecke geschmissen worden ist, war es im volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß nichts wert; als man aber erkannt hat, daß es wertvoll ist, war es dreißigtausend Gulden wert - und dreißigtausend Gulden waren damals viel. Wovon hing der Wert dazumal ab? Lediglich von dem, was für eine Ansicht man von dem Bilde gewann. Das Bild war nicht von seinem Orte weggebracht worden; nur die Menschen haben andere Gedanken darüber gekriegt. So kommt es bei nichts darauf an, was es «ist» unmittelbar. Und gerade die volkswirtschaftlichen Begriffe können Sie nie in Anlehnung an die äußere Realität entwickeln, sondern Sie müssen sie immer in Anlehnung an den volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß entwickeln. Und innerhalb eines Prozesses ändert sich ein Ding fortwährend. Man muß also sprechen von der volkswirtschaftlichen Zirkulation, bevor man auf solche Dinge kommt, wie Wert, Preis und so weiter. Nun sehen Sie in Volkswirtschaftslehren von heute, daß man mit Definitionen von Wert und Preis beginnt. Das erste ist aber. die Darstellung des volkswirtschaftlichen Prozesses; dann erst ergeben sich die Dinge, mit denen man heute die Sache anfängt.
Und nun, im Jahre 1919 konnte man denken, weil alles im Grunde genommen zerstört war, daß die Leute gesehen haben würden, daß man mit etwas Frischem anfangen muß. Nun, es war nicht der Fall. Die geringe Anzahl von Menschen, die dazumal daran glaubten, daß man neu anfangen muß, sind auch sehr bald in die Bequemlichkeit verfallen: Man kann ja doch nichts machen. — Mittlerweile trat die große Kalamität ein, die Valutaentwertung in den östlichen und mittleren Gegenden, und damit eine vollständige Umwälzung der Menschenschichtung; denn mit jeder weiteren Entwertung muß selbstverständlich derjenige, der von dem lebt, was mit Ultraviolett verglichen worden ist, verarmen. Und das geschieht auch, vielleicht mehr, als man es heute schon bemerkt. Das wird vollständig geschehen. Daher wird man vor allen Dingen hier gewiesen an den Begriff des sozialen Organismus, aus dem Grunde, weil sich ja zeigt, daß die Valutaentwertung durch die alte Staatsbegrenzung bestimmt wird. Die alte Staatsbegrenzung greift also ein in den volkswirtschaftlichen Prozeß. Diesen muß man begreifen, aber man muß erst den sozialen Organismus verstehen. Aber all die Nationalökonomien, von Adam Smith angefangen bis herauf zu den neuesten, rechnen eigentlich mit kleinen Gebieten als sozialen Organismen. Sie beachten da nicht einmal, daß, wenn man schon eine bloße Analogie wählt, diese stimmen muß. Die Menschen beachten gar nicht, daß sie stimmen muß. Haben Sie schon einen wirklichen ausgewachsenen Organismus gesehen, der so ist: Hier ist zum Beispiel ein Mensch, hier ist der zweite Mensch, hier ist der dritte Mensch und so weiter. Es wären niedliche Menschenorganismen, die in solcher Weise aneinanderkleben würden; das gibt es doch bei ausgewachsenen Organismen nicht. Das ist aber doch bei den Staaten der Fall. Organismen brauchen die Leere um sich herum bis zu dem anderen Organismus. Das, womit Sie die einzelnen Staaten vergleichen können, sind höchstens die Zellen des Organismus, und Sie können nur die ganze Erde als Wirtschaftskörper mit einem Organismus vergleichen. Das müßte beachtet werden. Das ist mit Händen zu greifen, seit wir Weltwirtschaft haben, daß wir die einzelnen Staaten nur mit Zellen vergleichen können. Die ganze Erde, als Wirtschaftsorganismus gedacht, ist der soziale Organismus.
Das wird nirgends ins Auge gefaßt. Denn die gesamte Volkswirtschaftslehre ist gerade dadurch hineingewachsen in etwas, was nicht der Wirklichkeit entspricht, weil man Prinzipien aufstellen will, die für eine einzelne Zelle gelten sollen. Daher finden Sie, wenn Sie die französische Volkswirtschaftslehre studieren, eine andere Konstitution, als wenn Sie die englische, die deutsche oder andere Volkswirtschaftslehren studieren. Aber als Volkswirtschafter brauchen wir schon ein Verständnis für den gesamten sozialen Organismus.
Und das wollte ich Ihnen heute als Einleitung sagen.

First Lecture
First, I would like to begin today with a kind of introduction and then move on tomorrow to what, in a certain sense, should form a whole: questions of national economics and social economics that people must ask themselves in the present day.
National economics, as it is currently referred to, is actually a relatively new creation. It essentially only came into being at a time when the economic life of modern nations had become extremely complicated compared to earlier economic conditions. And since we want to design this course primarily for students of economics, we must begin by pointing out this particular characteristic of economic thinking today.
We don't even need to go very far back in history to see how economic life changed, even during the 19th century alone, compared to earlier conditions. Just consider the fact that, in a certain sense, England, for example, was essentially modern in economic terms as early as the first half of the 19th century, so that relatively little in England's economic structure actually changed radically during the course of the 19th century. The major social issues that have arisen in recent times in connection with economic issues were already present in England in the first half of the 19th century, and even then, those who sought to think about social economics in the modern sense were able to pursue their studies in England, whereas such studies would have remained fruitless in, say, Germany at that time. In England, above all, the major trade relationships had already developed by the first third of the 19th century, and this development of the structure of trade had created a foundation for commercial capital within the English economy. In England, there was no need to start the new economy from any other point than that which had emerged as commercial capital from the consolidated trade relations that already existed, even in the first third of the 19th century. Building on this period, everything then developed for England with a certain consistency. However, we must not forget that the entire English economy was only possible on the basis of England's relationship with its colonies, particularly India. The entire English economy is inconceivable without England's relationship with India. In other words, this English economy, with its ability to generate large amounts of capital, is built on the fact that it has a country in the background that is, in a sense, economically virgin. We must not overlook this, especially when we now look across from the English economy to the German economy.
If you follow this, you will see that in the first third of the 19th century, for example, it was still essentially the same, corresponding to the economic habits that had developed since the Middle Ages. The economic habits and economic relationships within Germany in the first third of the 19th century were thoroughly old. As a result, the pace of economic life in Germany was different from that in England, for example, in the first third, indeed in the first half of the 19th century. In England, what can be called the calculation of rapidly changing lifestyles was already taking place in the first half of the century. The general trend of economic life remains essentially the same, but it is already calculated on the basis of rapidly changing habits. In Germany, these habits are still conservative. Economic life can still proceed at a snail's pace, as it is adapted to the fact that conditions in technical terms remain roughly the same for a long time and that needs do not change rapidly.
However, a change occurred in the second third of the 19th century. Under the influence of industrialization, conditions rapidly began to resemble those in England. In the first half of the 19th century, Germany was essentially an agricultural country, but it was rapidly transformed into an industrial country, much more rapidly than any other region on earth.
But this was linked to something else. One might say that in England, the transition to an industrial conception of the national economy developed instinctively; no one really knew how. It came about like a natural phenomenon. In Germany, medieval conditions still existed in the first third of the 19th century—Germany was an agrarian state; but while external economic conditions were such that they could almost still be called medieval, human thinking had changed profoundly. People became aware that something else had to come along, that what existed was no longer appropriate for the times; and so the transformation of economic conditions that took place in Germany in the second third of the 19th century was much more conscious than in England. People in Germany knew much more—in England they knew nothing at all—about how to enter into modern capitalism. If you were to read today what was discussed at that time, I would say, about entering into industrialism, you would get the impression: Yes, it is remarkable how people in Germany thought about it. — People saw it as nothing less than the complete liberation of humanity — they called it liberalism, they called it democracy — people saw it as nothing less than the salvation of humanity, breaking free from old ties, from the old corporate system, and moving to what was called the completely free position of man in economic life. That is why we never see a theory of economics in England such as that developed by people who drew their education from the heyday of this period, which I have characterized. Schmoller, Roscher, and others drew their views from the heyday of this liberalist economics. They consciously built up what was entirely built up in this sense. The English would have found such a theory of economics bland. One does not think about such things, he would have said. Therefore, just consider the radical difference when people in England—I will just take people who were already sufficiently theoretical, such as Beaconsfield—spoke about such questions, or when Richter, Lasker, or even Brentano spoke in Germany. In Germany, therefore, people consciously entered this second period.
Then came the third period, the actual state period. Isn't it true that as the last third of the 19th century approached, the German state basically consolidated itself through pure means of power? It was not what the idealists of the 1848s or even of the 1830s wanted that consolidated itself, but rather the state consolidated itself through pure means of power. This state also gradually and consciously took control of economic life, so that in the last third of the 19th century, economic life was completely permeated by the opposite principle than before. In the second third, it had developed under liberalist views, but now it developed entirely under the views of the state principle. This gave economic life in Germany its overall character, and there were elements of consciousness in this whole development. And yet the whole thing was unconscious.
The most important thing now was that this created a radical contrast, not just in thinking, but in the entire economy itself, between what the English economy was and what the Central European economy now was. Yes, but this contrast was the basis for how people did business with each other. The entire economy of the 19th century, as it developed into the 20th century, would have been inconceivable without this contrast between the West and the European center: that the way goods were sold was the way they were sold, the way they were marketed was the way they were marketed, the way they were manufactured was the way they were manufactured.
And so, gradually, the possibility of the English economy emerged on the basis of the possession of India, and now the possibility of expanding economic activity on the basis of the contrast between the Western and Central European economies. Economic life is not based on what one sees in one's immediate surroundings, but on the great mutual relationships in the world outside.
With this contrast, the world as a whole entered the global economy and – could not enter the global economy. For it was actually based on the instinctive elements that had developed and which I have just indicated with the contrast between England and Central Europe. In the 20th century, without the world knowing it, without noticing it, this contrast became more and more relevant, more and more profound. The contrast became more and more relevant, deeper and deeper, and people were faced with the big question: economic conditions had developed out of these contrasts, and they carried these contrasts more and more into the future; but at the same time, as the contrasts became greater and greater, it was impossible to do business with each other. That was the big question of the 20th century—the contrast had created the economy, the economy had magnified the contrast, the contrast needed a solution—the question then was: How do you resolve the contrasts? Well, historical development has shown that people were unable to resolve the question.
What I have just said could have been said in 1914, when there was peace. But instead of a solution, the result was an inability to find a solution of world historical significance. That is the disease that set in when one looks at the matter from the economic side.
Well, basically, all development is based on contradictions. I will mention just one such contrast: because the English economy had been consolidated much earlier than the Central European economy, the English were not able to offer such low prices for certain goods as was the case in Germany, so that a great contrast in competition arose; for “Made in Germany” was a question of competition. And when the war was over, the question arose: Yes, now that people had initially beaten each other's brains in, instead of looking for a solution to the contradictions, how could they now deal with the situation? I had to believe that people first had to be found who could understand what needed to be created in a different area than contradictions; for life is based on contradictions and can only exist if there are contradictions that interact with each other. And so, in 1919, one could come to say: Let us point out the opposites toward which world historical development actually tends, the opposites of the economic, the legal-political, and the spiritual-cultural, the opposites of the threefold structure.
What was basically right about the idea at that time that the threefold social order should be brought into as many minds as possible? Today I want to characterize this only externally: the most important thing was that the threefold social order should have been brought into as many minds as possible before the economic consequences that have since occurred arose. You must remember that when the threefold social order was first mentioned, we were not yet facing the currency difficulties of today; on the contrary, if the threefold social order had been understood at that time, they could never have arisen. But then again, it was impossible for people to understand something like this in a really practical sense. At that time, attempts were made to make the threefold social order understandable, and then people asked: Yes, that would all be fine, we understand that; but the first thing is to counteract the decline in currency. — Yes, one could only say to people: That is part of the threefold social order! Embrace the threefold social order, it is the only means of counteracting the decline of the currency! People asked how to do this, which is precisely what the threefold social order should have addressed. So they did not understand the threefold social order, even though they always claimed to.
And so today the situation is such that one must say: when speaking to personalities such as yourselves today, one can no longer speak in the same way as before, but today a different language is necessary. And that is what I would like to give you now in these lectures. I would like to show you how to think about these questions today, especially if you are young and can still contribute to what must be shaped in the coming times.
On the one hand, one can characterize a period, the 19th century, in terms of world historical and economic contrasts. But one could also go further back and then encompass the period when people began to think about national economy. If you take the history of national economy, you can see that in the past everything was done instinctively. It is actually only in recent times that the complexity of economic life has emerged, in which one feels it necessary to think about things.
Now I am actually speaking for students, speaking in such a way that students should be able to find their way into economics. That is why I would now like to say what is most important today. The time when people should have started thinking about economics was already the time when they no longer had the ideas to comprehend such a field as economics. People simply no longer had the ideas for it. I want to show you that this is the case by drawing on an example from natural science.
The situation is this: as human beings, we have our physical body, which is heavy, just as other physical bodies are heavy. It will be heavier after lunch than it is before lunch. You could even weigh it. This means that we participate in general heaviness. But we could not do much with this heaviness, which is the property of all ponderable matter, in the human body; at most, we could walk around in the world as automatons, but not as conscious beings. I have often said what is needed to form concepts that have value, and I have often said what is necessary for humans to think. The human brain weighs about 1400 grams when weighed on its own. If you press these 1400 grams onto the veins at the bottom of the skull, it will crush them to death. You could not live for a moment if the human brain were such that it pressed down with its entire 1400 grams. It is fortunate for humans that Archimedes' principle exists, which states that every body loses as much weight in water as the weight of the liquid it displaces. So if you have a heavy body in water, it loses as much of its weight as a body of water of the same size weighs. The brain floats in cerebral fluid and loses 1380 grams in the process, because that is the weight of the body of water that is the same size as the human brain. The brain presses only 20 grams onto the base, and the base can bear that weight. But if we now ask ourselves: What is the purpose of this? – then we must say: With a brain that is merely ponderable mass, we would not be able to think. We do not think with what is heavy matter, but we think with buoyancy. Matter must first lose its heaviness before we can think. We think with what flies away from the earth.
But we are conscious of our whole body. How do we become conscious of our whole body? There are twenty-five trillion red blood cells in our entire body. These twenty-five trillion red blood cells are very small, but they are heavy because they contain iron. Each of these twenty-five trillion red blood cells floats in the blood serum and loses as much weight as it displaces in fluid. This in turn creates buoyancy in each individual blood cell, twenty-five trillion times over. We are conscious throughout our entire body through what rises up. So we can say that when we consume food, it must first be largely lightened and converted so that it can serve us. That is what the organism requires.
We have forgotten how to think in this way and to regard it as something authoritative in an age when it has become necessary to think in terms of national economy. From then on, only ponderable substances were taken into account, and no thought was given to the transformation that a substance undergoes in an organism, for example, in terms of its weight, by having buoyancy.
But there is something else. If you still remember your physics studies today, you will know that in physics we talk about the spectrum. A prism produces this band of colors: red, orange, yellow, green, blue, indigo, violet. As far as red to violet, the spectrum appears illuminated. But you know that it is assumed that beyond the range that has light effects, there are the so-called ultra-red rays and beyond violet, the ultraviolet rays. So when someone talks only about light, they do not cover the whole of this phenomenon; they must talk about how light is polarized in two directions; they must talk about how, outside of red, light sinks into heat, and outside of violet, it sinks into chemical effects and actually disappears as light. So when someone gives a mere theory of light, they are giving only a partial picture; but we are also giving a false theory of light. At the very time when one should have begun to think about national economy, physics, physical thinking, was in such a state that a false theory of light emerged.
I have cited this to you because there is a valid analogy here. Please consider not the national economy, but the sparrow economy or swallow economy! That is also a kind of economy, but this economy in the animal kingdom does not extend far into the human realm. In the case of hamsters, we can even speak of animal capitalism. The essence of animal economy is that nature provides the products and the animal, as an individual, takes them. Humans still protrude into this animal economy, but they must get out of it.
The economy that we can initially refer to as a human economy can be compared to what is visible as light in the spectrum, while we must compare what still extends into nature to what extends into the ultra-red. Here, for example, we extend into the field of agriculture, into the field of economic geography, and so on. We cannot define economics strictly in this way. Economics extends into an area that must be understood in a completely different way. That is one side of the coin.
On the other hand, however, especially under our more complicated economic conditions, we have gradually come to the point where economic thinking is actually falling away from human beings. Just as light ceases to appear as light in the ultraviolet range, so human activity in economics ceases to be purely economic. I have often described how this came about. This phenomenon actually only began in the 19th century. Until then, economic life was still quite dependent on individual human competence. A bank prospered if an individual at the bank was capable. Individuals still meant something. I have often told the charming example of how an envoy of the King of France once came to Rothschild. He wanted to take out a loan there. Rothschild was negotiating with a leather merchant and said, when he was told about the envoy of the King of France: Well, he should wait a little. Now the man was terribly depressed. He should wait, there is a leather merchant inside! When the servant came out and said that, he did not believe him at all. Yes, tell Mr. Rothschild inside that I come as an envoy of the King of France! The servant brought the answer: Yes, you should wait. Then he jumps in and says: I am the envoy of the King of France. — Rothschild replies: Please, sit down, take a chair! — Yes, I am the envoy of the King of France! — Please, take two chairs!
Yes, that was what happened in economic life at that time, consciously placed in the human personality. But things have changed. Today, the individual personality has very little influence on the big picture of economic life. Human economic activity has already penetrated very deeply into what I would like to compare with ultraviolet light. And that is what works as capital as such. The masses of capital work as such. Above economic life there is an ultra-economic life, which is essentially conditioned by the inherent power of the masses of capital, so that we must say: if we really want to understand economic life today, we must see it as lying in the middle between two areas, one of which leads down into nature and the other up into capital. And in between lies what we must understand as the actual economic life.
But this shows that we did not even have the concept to properly define economics itself, to properly place it within the whole of knowledge. For we will see that, curiously enough, only this area, which does not actually enter into economic activity, which can be compared to the ultra-red, only this can be grasped by the human mind. One can think about it in the same way as other processes: how to grow oats, how to grow barley, and so on, how best to extract raw materials in mining. Basically, one can only think about this correctly with the mind that one has become accustomed to using in modern science.
This is of immense importance! Just think back to what I gave as the concept that is needed in science. We enjoy heavy substances as food. The fact that they can serve us is based on the fact that they continuously lose their weight in us, that they are completely transformed. But this goes so far that they are transformed differently in each organ. The transformation in the liver is different from that in the brain or the lungs. The organism is differentiated and the conditions become different for each substance in each organ. We have a continuous change in quality in the change of the organs.
This is roughly how it is when we talk within an economic whole, say, about the value of a commodity. Just as it is nonsense to define any substance, say carbon, and then ask: How does it behave in the human body? Except for its ponderability, carbon is something completely different than it is here or there in the outside world—just as one cannot ask about the value of a commodity. This is different, whether the commodity is in a store or has been transported here or there.
The ideas of economics must be very flexible. We must break the habit of constructing terms that can be defined. We must realize that we are dealing with a living process and that we must transform the terms in the living process. However, attempts were made to grasp value, price, production, consumption, and so on with the ideas that people had. But they were useless. That is why we have basically been unable to achieve an economic theory. We cannot answer questions such as “What is value? What is price?” using the concepts we have become accustomed to, because we must constantly consider what has value in circulation; we must constantly consider the price that corresponds to a value in circulation. And you see, if you ask about the simple physical properties of carbon, you will know nothing about what happens in the lungs, for example, even though it is also in the lungs, because the whole configuration becomes something completely different in the lungs. Similarly, iron found in a mine is something completely different from iron in the economic process. The economy is based on something completely different than what iron “is.” But such unstable factors must be taken into account.
I once came to a family about forty-five years ago. They showed me a picture. The picture had been lying on the floor for thirty years, I think. As long as it lay there and no one knew anything about the picture other than that it was something that had been thrown into a corner, it was worthless in the economic process; but when people realized that it was valuable, it was worth thirty thousand guilders—and thirty thousand guilders was a lot of money back then. What did its value depend on back then? Solely on the opinion people formed of the painting. The painting had not been removed from its place; it was only people who had changed their minds about it. So nothing depends on what something “is” in the immediate sense. And it is precisely economic concepts that you can never develop on the basis of external reality, but must always develop on the basis of the economic process. And within a process, a thing is constantly changing. So you have to talk about economic circulation before you get to things like value, price, and so on. Now, in today's economic theories, you see that they start with definitions of value and price. But the first thing is the representation of the economic process; only then do the things with which we start today emerge.
And now, in 1919, one might think that because everything was basically destroyed, people would have seen that something new had to be started. Well, that was not the case. The small number of people who believed at the time that a new start was necessary very soon fell into complacency: there was nothing that could be done anyway. — In the meantime, the great calamity occurred, the devaluation of currency in the eastern and central regions, and with it a complete upheaval of the social strata; for with each further devaluation, those who live on what has been compared to ultraviolet light must, of course, become poorer. And that is happening, perhaps more than is already noticeable today. It will happen completely. Therefore, above all, we are referred here to the concept of the social organism, for the reason that it is evident that currency devaluation is determined by the old state boundaries. The old state boundaries thus intervene in the economic process. This must be understood, but first one must understand the social organism. But all national economies, from Adam Smith to the most recent ones, actually consider small areas to be social organisms. They do not even consider that if one chooses a mere analogy, it must be correct. People do not consider at all that it must be correct. Have you ever seen a real, fully grown organism that is like this: Here, for example, is one human being, here is the second human being, here is the third human being, and so on. They would be cute human organisms that would stick together in this way; but this does not exist in fully grown organisms. However, this is the case with states. Organisms need the empty space around them up to the other organism. The only thing you can compare individual states to are the cells of an organism, and you can only compare the whole earth as an economic entity to an organism. This must be taken into account. Since we have a global economy, it has become obvious that we can only compare individual states to cells. The whole earth, conceived as an economic organism, is the social organism.
This is not taken into account anywhere. For this very reason, the entire field of economics has grown into something that does not correspond to reality, because people want to establish principles that are supposed to apply to a single cell. Therefore, when you study French economics, you will find a different constitution than when you study English, German, or other economic theories. But as economists, we need an understanding of the entire social organism.
And that is what I wanted to say to you today by way of introduction.
